The role of trading system
between Japan, china and US:
The U.S.-Japan Trading
Relationship and Its Effects :
- The historical relationship between
the United States and Japan since 1945 has always been one-sided.
Since World War II Japan has tended to assume that it was (at least
in security terms) a dependent partner of the United States. From
that standpoint, Japan could be a "free rider" on U.S. security and
foreign policy protection and largesse. Equally and oppositely, the
United States has generally believed that because Japan was
dependent, it did not need to be consulted about matters of global
security and high policy.
- It could be asked to participate in
U.S. and United Nations peacekeeping and peacemaking endeavors
after the fact. The United States could concert with other nations,
Russia and the European allies, and then ask Japan to help pay for
the operations that had been agreed upon. Both of these assumptions
obviously represent inappropriate responses to the changed
relationship between the two countries. The future success of the
U.S.-Japan relationship requires mutuality and reciprocity of
interests and symmetry of behavior that have not yet been fully
understood, and certainly not acted upon, by either partner.
1. THE GROWTH OF THE TRADING
RIVALRY :
- The origins of the U.S.-Japan
tension over trade are relatively recent in character. The
essential problem that the Japanese economy presents to the world
trading system is that the economy operates with too high a level
of national savings.' This means that Japan cannot consume the
produce of its own industry, and consequently, this produce has to
be sent abroad as exports. This was not a major problem in the
1960s and early 1970s, because during those times, high Japanese
private investment absorbed national savings. Private corporations
bought investment goods, new capital, and equipment, and the
failure of private and government consumption did not matter.
Japanese productive capacity was fully utilized in making new
machines. There was, as a result, no significant Japanese trade
surplus. The situation changed in the mid- to late 1970s and early
1980s. At that time, private investment spending declined, but it
was replaced by high government spending. Government purchases
absorbed Japanese savings. Low consumer spending (high savings)
presented no problem because the government purchased large amounts
of goods. Again, there was no large Japanese trade surplus.
- The problem grew greatly in 1984,
however, when the Japanese government reduced its deficit spending,
and business did not take up the slack by increasing investment, as
it had done in the 1960s and early 1970s. From the mid-1980s on,
therefore, Japan no longer consumed the produce of its own
industry, and this produce then had to be sent abroad as exports.
At that point, the high level of Japanese savings (and the
correlatively low level of Japanese consumption) created problems
for the nation's trading partners. This was the beginning of the
problem of persistent imbalances in the Japanese trading account
with the United States and other countries.
II. "SHARKS AND FISHES"?
The problem that the United States
currently faces is to turn around the trading deficit. The overall
Japanese merchandise trade deficit may reach $160 billion in
1993-94.6 This will present problems for other countries, as well
as for the United States. The situation is analogous to that
depicted in the "Sharks and Fishes" computer game.7 In that game,
the objective is to maintain ecological balance between populations
of sharks and fish. It is assumed that fish live on abundant
plankton and sharks live on the fish. Players are then asked, at
the outset of the game, to choose the number of sharks and fish,
the life spans of the two species, and the breeding and feeding
times of the sharks and fish. With these selected, the computer
begins its iterations, with the populations of sharks and fish
oscillating over time. Frequently after about 4,000 iterations, the
sharks consume all the fish, but then, as a result, the sharks also
die, and the game comes to an end. This game presents a morality
tale for the United States and Japan. It makes it clear that if the
U.S. market is going to serve as the continued sustenance for
Japanese industry, it must be allowed to grow rapidly enough to
regenerate itself. If U.S. industry does not sell enough, either
domestically or abroad, U.S. incomes will fall to levels that will
not sustain large Japanese exports to the United States. Then Japan
and the United States will both lose.
III. THE U.S. AGENDA
:
- Of course, there is much the United
States must do to redress its part of the trade imbalance.
Obviously, it must cut its government deficit (which was over $290
billion in 1992),8 and it should seek to increase its household
savings rate, which has been hovering between three and five
percent of the gross national product (GNP). If household savings
rose, the pool of investible funds would increase and the
government deficit (which trenches upon these funds) would be less
worrisome. For example, in the late 1970s, even though Japanese
government deficits reached five percent of the GNP (about the same
percentage as the current U.S. figure), there was no huge trade
deficit because Japanese private savings more than made up for the
shortfall in public funds. Japanese consumers restrained
consumption even when the government failed to do so
IV. THE JAPANESE AGENDA
- A solution to the trade imbalance
would also require Japan to recirculate the surpluses it has
gained. Axiomatically, Japanese exports are balanced by short term
borrowing in the United States and foreign money markets. In a
schedule sense, equilibrium could be maintained by Japan cutting
its borrowing abroad, but this would not solve the long term
problem. A solution to this more fundamental imbalance involves
recirculating the surpluses in a more permanent way. A major
systemic balancing issue is involved here, and all past financial
hegemons have faced it. In the nineteenth century, Britain
recirculated the surpluses it had gained in trade by investing and
loaning money to trading partners. But these investments had to be
financed, and the loans had to be repaid. By 1910, Britain had
enabled all its debtors, except India, to repay loans by running a
trade surplus in the British home market. One after another,
Germany, the United States, Canada, Australia, New Zealand, and
South Africa gained surpluses in trading with Britain
V. LONG TERM HARMONY BETWEEN THE
UNITED STATES AND JAPAN?
- But the long term looks much more
harmonious, for political-military as well as trading reasons. From
a traditional balance of power standpoint, the tension between the
United States and Japan will ebb as China becomes a more
significant world actor. The pressure on two feuding countries to
compromise their differences because of a rising third power did
not occur between 1910 and 1914. Germany and Britain were not
brought together by the rise of either Russia or the United States.
The United States turned out to be at best an episodic participant
in world and European politics, and Russia, after the 1917
revolution, was isolated. Given the United States' preoccupation
with hemispheric affairs in 1914 and its return to "normalcy" in
1920, foreigners recognized that U.S. power could not be used as a
threat to bring cooperation between Germany and England. Nor,
despite Chamberlain's wish for an anti-Soviet group, did Soviet
Russia serve as a catalyst to bring feuding Europeans together
VI. GLOBALIZATION, COMMERCE, AND
DEMOCRATIZATION
- This does not mean that the world
does not have myriad problems ahead of it in the short term. The
G-7 has been a failure. GATT negotiations have been derailed and
may not get on track again. French opposition to an agricultural
agreement to reduce surpluses remains strong. Economic conflict
among the major trading partners is rising. Economic imbalances are
increasing, not diminishing. It is still uncertain whether either
the Japanese or U.S. political systems will be strong enough to
make the necessary but tough decisions to reform, economically and
politically. Japan will be asked to change its policies in major
ways and a government in Washington that no longer is dominated by
either free market or "security comes first" advocates will have to
press Congress and the people of the United States to achieve
reforms at home.
U.S.–Japan and U.S.–China
trade conflict :
- Japan in the 1950s through the
1990s and China since the late 1970s have followed similar – and
similarly successful – strategies of promoting economic growth
through rapid acquisition of advanced foreign technology and
expansion of manufactured exports. While other Asian countries have
done likewise, in some cases with exports growing as rapidly and
for as long, Japan and China have presented special challenges to
the GATT/WTO trading system because their shares of world exports
have been so large and the associated bilateral trade imbalances
with the United States so conspicuous. In both political and
economic terms, these large imbalances seem to contradict the
GATT/WTO principle of reciprocity, which involves a balance of
market-access concessions across major players in the system.
- During their respective periods of
rapid export growth, Japan and China each accounted for a major
share of total world exports. As of 2007, China’s share of world
merchandise exports had soared to 8.9%, less than Germany’s 9.7%
share but topping the U.S. share of 8.5% as well as Japan’s 5.2%,
in each of the latter three cases from a much larger economy (WTO,
2008b). Given the sharp drop in global import demand following the
2008 onset of the global financial crisis, China may not surpass
Japan’s 1980s peak of around 10%. However, U.S. imports from China
in 2008 ($337.8 billion) still exceeded their level in 2007 ($321.5
billion); the 2008 bilateral trade imbalance ($266.3 billion) also
exceeded 2007’s record figure, although only by $10 billion