In: Computer Science
1 INTRODUCTION
The red tape literature can be characterized as ‘one of the most popular and even defining topics for empirical researchers in public management’ but it also has ‘some troubling knowledge gaps’ (Brewer et al. 2012, p. 289). One of these gaps is the institutional context that may either mitigate or exacerbate red tape. Another is the focus on red tape in public organizations, especially because most national and supranational better regulation programmes primarily aim to reduce red tape for private organizations (Helm 2006; Radaelli 2010). The main aim of this study is to fill these gaps by examining how institutional context explains cross‐national differences in perceptions of red tape in the private sector.
We follow a recent stream of literature that conceptualizes red tape as being subjective in nature (e.g., Kaufmann and Feeney 2012, 2014). For example, Pandey and Kingsley (2000, p. 782) define organizational red tape as ‘impressions on the part of managers that formalization (in the form of burdensome rules and procedures) is detrimental to the organization’. While most existing studies have focused on organizational formalization as a red tape driver (e.g., Pandey and Scott 2002; Kaufmann and Feeney 2012), we are interested in understanding how a country's institutional context affects perceived red tape created by government rules, regulations, and procedures.
Although public administration scholars have given scant attention to the concept of red tape in the private sector, the World Economic Forum's Executive Opinion Survey (Schwab 2014), in which thousands of business leaders in almost 150 countries participated, shows that the perceived burden of complying with governmental administrative requirements differs considerably across countries. On a 7‐point Likert scale (with 7 indicating ‘extremely burdensome’), executives from Venezuela scored the highest with an average of 5.4 while the lowest was an average of 1.8 for Qatar executives. While these figures indicate variation in red tape perceptions across countries, it remains unclear to what extent country‐level institutions inform these differences.
Drawing on institutional theory, we argue that a variety of country‐level institutions affect perceptions of red tape. We posit that while rules and procedures are a necessary condition to do business, the ‘constraints that human beings impose on themselves’ (North 1990, p. 5)—the institutions in a particular country—affect basic attitudes toward those rules and procedures and, ultimately, perceptions of red tape in the private sector. The institutions driving red tape perceptions can be formal and informal. Formal institutions include constitutions, contracts, and form of government (e.g., North 1990, 1991; Lowndes 1996; Farrell and Héritier 2003), while informal institutions include ‘traditions, customs, moral values, religious beliefs, and all other norms of behavior that have passed the test of time’ (Pejovich 1999, p. 166).
Following Kostova (1997), we focus on those formal and informal institutions that are most relevant for the context of our study. Specifically, we include three formal institutions (formalization, rule enforcement effectiveness, and federalism) and three informal institutions (corruption, political ideology, and culture) that are reflected in both the existing red tape literature (e.g., Bozeman 2000; Bozeman and Feeney 2011) and comparative research on institutions at the country level. The formal institutions capture rules and government structures, while the informal institutions focus on ideology and culture. While other measures of formal and informal institutions could be included in a study on institutions and red tape (e.g., institutional age, political contentiousness, and number of regulatory bodies), we believe that our set of formal and informal institutions captures a wide range of relevant country‐level institutional dimensions.
Formalization captures the number of written rules in an organization or within specific rule domains at the (supra‐)national level (e.g., Pugh et al. 1968; Kaufmann and Van Witteloostuijn 2012, 2016) and is positively associated with red tape (Bozeman 2000). The effectiveness of rule enforcement also plays a part in red tape. If rules are not enforced effectively, their associated compliance burden is more likely to be viewed as excessive and pointless by firms when compared to a situation of effective rule enforcement that creates a level playing field (La Porta et al. 2000). The third formal institution that probably affects red tape in the private sector is whether a state is unitary or federal. Generally speaking, interdependencies between different levels of government are more complex in federal states (e.g., Chubb 1985; Nelson 1990), which implies higher levels of red tape.
Informal institutions can include norms such as corruption, political ideology, and culture. Studies in development economics assume that higher levels of corruption are associated with more red tape (e.g., Guriev 2004). Furthermore, societies characterized by a more conservative view of the role of government are generally more critical of government rules and regulations (Michaud et al. 2009; Gauchat 2012). As a result, red tape perceptions should be higher in these societies compared to societies with more liberal views on the role of government. In societies with a high level of collectivism, group interests take precedence over an individual's interests (e.g., Hofstede 2001). Since government rules and regulations primarily aim to serve the public interest (Bozeman 2000), we expect that more collectivist societies are associated with lower levels of perceived red tape. Prior research has also found that societies high in uncertainty avoidance prefer extensive rules and regulations to mitigate uncertain situations (e.g., House et al. 2004), which means that the burden of government rules and regulations (e.g., red tape) is likely to be lower in high uncertainty avoidance societies.
We conduct an analysis of red tape perceptions in the private sector using data from six sources including the World Economic Forum and the World Bank. In so doing, we are conducting the first comparative cross‐country study on red tape. This study provides valuable insights into red tape dynamics for both scholars and policy‐makers. In the following section, we introduce our hypotheses linking research on formal and informal institutions to red tape. Next, we present our data and methods. We then present our results and conclude with a discussion of how this research informs theory and practice.
2 INSTITUTIONS AND RED TAPE
Externally mandated rules, procedures, and regulations are necessary in the business domain to facilitate activities of the firm. Government rules often aim to create a level playing field and reduce uncertainty for firms, but can also be perceived by business leaders as dysfunctional (Bozeman 1993, 2012). We argue that perceptions of red tape created by government rules are affected by a country's institutional framework. We focus on three formal (formalization, rule enforcement effectiveness, and federalism) and three informal institutions (corruption, political ideology, and culture) that theory and previous research indicate are particularly relevant for the study of red tape in the private sector (e.g., Bozeman 2000; Pandey and Scott 2002; Bozeman and Feeney 2011).
2.1 Formal institutions and red tape
2.1.1 Formalization
Formalization, denoting ‘the extent to which rules, procedures, instructions and communications are written’ (Pugh et al. 1968, p. 75), is intertwined with the concept of red tape. Research indicates that at the organizational level, higher levels of formalization are associated with more red tape (Bozeman 2000). Red tape theory assumes that government formalization in the form of external rules and regulations is the main driver of red tape for public and private organizations alike (Bozeman 1993; Bozeman and Feeney 2011). Taken together, these arguments imply that government rules and regulations are an important driver of red tape in the private sector.
Studies in the rule ecology domain conceptualize formal rules as belonging to populations of rules that (co‐)evolve (March et al. 2000; Van Witteloostuijn and de Jong 2010; Kaufmann and Van Witteloostuijn 2011). Kaufmann and Van Witteloostuijn (2012) draw on this line of research to propose a conceptual model that highlights how European and national rule stocks jointly affect organizational red tape. Kaufmann and Van Witteloostuijn (2016) suggest that there is an increased chance of overlap and redundancies in formalization if the same subject matter is regulated at different hierarchical levels, thus leading to more red tape. Many countries have initiated regulatory reform programmes aimed at reducing red tape stemming from supranational rules, national rules, and the implementation of supranational rules at the national level, especially in the business domain (Brewer and Walker 2010; De Jong and Van Witteloostuijn 2015), thus increasing different levels of rules on the same subject matter.
Moreover, the relationship between external rules and organizational red tape has been tested in the context of the external control model of red tape (Bozeman 1993; Bozeman and Feeney 2011). This model seeks to explain how the external environment drives organizational red tape. Brewer et al. (2012) find that organizations facing higher levels of external control report higher levels of red tape, and that this relationship is mediated by informal communication and devolved management. Similarly, de Jong and Van Witteloostuijn (2015) focus on the impact of external regulation on perceived red tape in the context of Dutch private organizations. The authors argue that red tape perceptions are driven not only by the cost of regulation, but also by inconsistencies and changes in regulation. In sum, there is strong evidence in the red tape literature to suggest that formalization in the form of government rules, regulations, and procedures is positively associated with red tape:
H1: There will be a positive association between country‐level formalization and perceptions of red tape in the private sector.
2.1.2 Rule enforcement effectiveness
Effective rule enforcement is a necessary condition for countries to ensure that government rules and regulations achieve their functional goals and minimize red tape. La Porta et al. (2000) argue that the enforcement of laws is equally as important as the content of those laws. How effectively government rules and regulations are enforced differs substantially across countries, for at least two reasons. First, there is a straightforward relationship between the amount of resources available for rule enforcement and enforcement effectiveness. Understaffed rule enforcement agencies and court systems will have a harder time identifying and taking action against rule‐breakers than agencies with generous budgets (Stigler 1970). Thus, rule enforcement quality is expected to be higher in richer countries (La Porta et al. 1996).
Second, political pressures and preferences may hamper rule enforcement. Shotts and Wiseman (2010) argue that bureaucratic agents can promote or dampen their political superior's interests by deciding whether or not a certain case will be investigated in the first place. Even if a case of possible non‐compliance is brought to the attention of agents such as prosecutors or regulators, political preferences may block effective rule enforcement. For example, Gerber et al. (2004) discuss how voters passed a proposition in 1986 that made English the official language in California. Yet, the new law was not supported by key officials, and was barely enforced. When a complaint was filed with the Attorney General about trilingual election materials in San Francisco, the Attorney General responded that the proposition ‘required only that official publications be made available in English, not that they be offered in English only’ (Gerber et al. 2004, pp. 43–44). This is an example of effective rule enforcement being undermined by political context.
The relationship between compliance burden and achieving the rule's functional object, or goal, becomes particularly strained in the absence of effective enforcement. If high‐quality rule enforcement ensures a level playing field, then a lack thereof is likewise associated with arbitrariness, obscurity, and ambiguity. Indeed, firms may wonder why they are incurring the costs of complying with poorly enforced rules in the first place. We expect poorly enforced rules to be associated with increased perceptions of red tape.
H2: There will be a negative association between the effectiveness of rule enforcement in a country and perceptions of red tape in the private sector.
2.1.3 Federalism
Type of government is another formal institution that probably affects red tape. The literature distinguishes between unitary and federal states, where the former centralizes decision‐making authority while the latter delegates more decision‐making to local governments. The key difference between the two types is not necessarily the devolution of power to local governments as such, but rather ‘the existence within federal states of institutional guarantees that the division of powers will not be arbitrarily changed without the consent of territorial sub‐units’ (Castles and McKinlay 1979, p. 174). As a result, the interdependencies between different levels of government can be considered more complex in federal than unitary states (Scholz and Wei 1986; Nelson 1990). This additional institutional complexity impacts red tape in the private sector in three ways.
First, rules may be more likely to entail red tape from the outset in federal systems due to what Bozeman (1993) refers to as negative sum process and negative sum compromise. Negative sum process relates to those instances where participation requirements are so extensive that even stakeholders having no interest to participate are required to do so. As such, rules aimed at enhancing participation in a federal system become a source of red tape themselves. Negative sum compromise occurs when a rule is intended to serve so many different objectives that it ends up serving none (Bozeman and Feeney 2011). While this type of dynamic holds for most if not all rule‐making situations, it is particularly likely to occur in federal states that are multi‐layered and ‘often criticized for producing deadlock, slowing down decision‐making processes, or producing inefficient policy solutions’ (Biela et al. 2014, p. 505).
Second, policy change is more difficult to achieve in a federal system where stipulated majority requirements are more pronounced, multiple political levers are in place that can defeat proposals for change, and the central government's political competence is limited as compared to unitary states (Castles and McKinlay 1979). The inability of federal policy‐makers to change policies quickly may result in rule‐evolved red tape. Rule‐evolved red tape exists when good rules go ‘bad’ (Bozeman 1993). There are many reasons why a rule that was initially effective becomes dysfunctional over time. For example, rule drift occurs when the meaning of a rule gets lost over time. Or unforeseen changes in the rule's functional object or implementation can lead to rule‐evolved red tape (Bozeman and Feeney 2011). The most effective way to remedy rule‐evolved red tape is to change or abolish the rules that have become dysfunctional. However, it can take longer to change or abolish an ineffective rule in federal states.
Third, the institutional requirements of federal states can lead to variations in formal institutions at the local level. For example, Nelson (1990, p. 444) argues that US local governments have been characterized as fragmented, like ‘a “crazy‐quilt” of overlapping boundaries and with little in the way of coordination and cooperation among local authorities’. The inefficiencies caused by this type of institutional design are exacerbated by the fact that best practices are not easily transferable from one local government to another within a federal system. Hendriks and Tops (1999) note that institutional reforms in the Federal Republic of Germany are created through bottom‐up rather than top‐down processes, limiting the transfer of best practices between local governments to highly non‐specific models. Given the complexity and multi‐layered rules and regulations in federal states, we expect red tape to be more pronounced in federal states as opposed to unitary states.
H3: There will be a positive association between federal states and perceptions of red tape in the private sector.
2.2 Informal institutions and red tape
Informal institutions guide human behaviour and decision‐making processes (North 1990; Crossland and Hambrick 2011). Drawing from the red tape literature, we focus on three informal institutions: political ideology, corruption, and culture. We operationalize culture with two dimensions: individualism and uncertainty avoidance.
2.2.1 Political ideology
A key assumption in the literature is that most red tape derives from government rules and regulations (Bozeman and Feeney 2011; Brewer et al. 2012). There are two related scenarios in which government rules may increase perceptions of red tape for businesses. In the first scenario, government regulates policy areas that restrict firm behaviour and does so in a way that is perceived by firms as being ineffective. In this case, red tape is the result of poorly designed rules (rule‐inception red tape) or rules that turn bad over time (rule‐evolved red tape) (Bozeman 1993). In the second scenario, perceptions of red tape result from government rules and regulations in a certain policy area that firms believe should not be regulated in the first place. Instead, firms may argue that better outcomes can be achieved through alternatives to regulation, such as voluntary compliance or industry self‐regulation (e.g., Gunningham and Rees 1997). It is important to realize that in both scenarios firms may perceive red tape merely because they are opposed to government interference, either in a particular form or more generally. Hence, red tape complaints should not be taken at face value without taking into account overall rule costs and benefits (Bozeman 2012).
Assessments of the effectiveness and appropriateness of government rules and regulations are intertwined with ideological stances on the role of government. Individuals with a more conservative ideology prefer smaller government and greater market freedom, whereas liberals prefer government to have a greater influence on society (Lavertu and Moynihan 2013). Many conservatives argue that the welfare state undermines the vitality of a competitive, private economy and results in a lack of self‐reliance among citizens, in particular the poor, and stifles businesses from being innovative (Skitka and Tetlock 1993). Generally speaking, conservatives feel that government is trying to do too much and it does so ineffectively, resulting in opposition to government regulation (Michaud et al. 2009; Gauchat 2012). In comparison, liberals view government regulation as necessary to ensure fairness, equity, environmental health, or worker safety. This line of reasoning is supported by Kaufmann and Tummers (2017), who found that individuals with a more conservative political orientation are more dissatisfied with organizational red tape than are more liberal individuals. Thus, we expect that in countries with a more conservative view of the role of government, business leaders will be more likely to perceive government rules and regulations as entailing red tape.
H4: There will be a positive association between a more conservative political ideology in a country and perceptions of red tape in the private sector.
2.2.2 Corruption
Corruption is arguably one of the most commonly mentioned informal institutions related to red tape. The relationship between corruption and red tape is complex as the two are linked reciprocally: ‘red tape makes corruption possible, and corrupt bureaucrats may increase the extent of red tape so they can extract additional bribes’ (Mauro 1998, p. 12). Corrupt bureaucrats can use red tape to slow down administrative procedures and demand ‘speed money’ in exchange for minimizing administrative delays (Mauro 1995).
Existing research on administrative delay argues that red tape is reflected in how long it takes an organization to perform core organizational tasks. Bozeman et al. (1992, p. 292) note that ‘the irritation with red tape is not necessarily, then, inherent in rules and procedures but is a response to delays caused by superfluous rules and procedures, as well as delays in the decision‐making process’. Administrative delay is typically operationalized as a set of questions asking respondents to indicate the amount of time it takes to carry out specific tasks inside the organization, such as purchasing equipment, contracting for services, and hiring personnel (Bozeman and Kingsley 1998; DeHart‐Davis and Bozeman 2001). Yet, cumbersome interactions with government officials to acquire permits or licences can create delays within the firm, driving red tape perceptions. If corrupt officials hold up administrative procedures, these procedures are likely to be viewed as entailing red tape, even if the procedures themselves are streamlined. This leads to the following hypothesis:
H5: There will be a positive association between a country's level of corruption and perceptions of red tape in the private sector.
2.2.3 Culture
Culture guides human behaviour as it provides members of society with schematic, mental models about what is appropriate versus inappropriate, legitimate versus illegitimate, and good versus bad. These mental models are acquired in the early years of an individual's life and, hence, have a strong impact on an individual's behaviour and choices.
Studies in the cross‐cultural domain define national culture in terms of taxonomies consisting of several cultural dimensions. One of the most influential and commonly used taxonomies is Hofstede (2001), who distinguishes four cultural dimensions, namely collectivism versus individualism, uncertainty avoidance, power distance, and masculinity versus femininity. In line with Kostova's (1997) recommendations as well as prior research in the business domain (e.g., Mueller and Thomas 2000; Crossland and Hambrick 2011), we focus on two of these institutional dimensions that are theoretically linked to perceptions of business red tape: individualism versus collectivism and uncertainty avoidance.
2.2.4 Collectivism versus individualism
A fundamental and widely studied cultural dimension is individualism versus collectivism which relates to the extent that members of a society are supposed to look after themselves or are embedded in groups (Hofstede 2001; Triandis 2001). In collectivistic countries, the interests of the group are considered to be more important than individual interests. As a result, the individual has duties and mutual obligations to other group members and a strong need to maintain harmony in the group (Markus and Kitayama 1991; Hofstede 2001; Oyserman et al. 2002). In contrast, personal independence, rights above duties, personal autonomy, promoting self‐reliance, and self‐fulfilment are more central in individualistic countries (e.g., Triandis 2001).
Entrepreneurs perceive government rules and regulations differently based on individualism and collectivism. Prior research indicates that entrepreneurial behaviours are associated more strongly with individualism than with collectivism (e.g., Hayton et al. 2002; Pinillos and Reyes 2011; Terjesen et al. 2016). This positive association is directly linked to traits common among business people and entrepreneurs, such as a desire for autonomy, independence, and a need for personal development (e.g., Block et al. 2013; Simón‐Moya et al. 2014). Licht and Siegel (2006) suggest that entrepreneurs’ job satisfaction largely depends on levels of perceived independence and autonomy. Similarly, Morris et al. (1993) note that individual autonomy encourages perseverance needed to pursue business and entrepreneurial activities. Since government rules and regulations generally limit freedom of action, independence, and autonomy, it is likely that—notwithstanding the fact that many of these rules are effective and meet valid objectives—external rules are more quickly perceived as red tape in countries that are more individualistic in nature. Accordingly, we hypothesize:
H6a: There will be a positive association between the level of individualism in a country and perceptions of red tape in the private sector.
2.2.5 Uncertainty avoidance
Uncertainty avoidance is the degree to which members of a society feel uncomfortable with and even threatened by uncertainty and ambiguity (Hofstede 2001). Individuals in high uncertainty avoidant countries possess a greater proclivity for consistency, orderliness, and structure and attempt to reduce uncertainty by relying on established social norms, rituals, and bureaucratic practices (e.g., Hofstede 2001; House et al. 2004). In societies characterized by low uncertainty avoidance, people are generally more open to accept change, attach less value to predictability, and are more willing to take risks (Hofstede 2001).
One way for individuals to reduce uncertainty is to rely on rule‐based mechanisms (Wennberg et al. 2013), which involve higher degrees of rules and regulations (Baptista 2007) that make clear how individuals are expected to act (House et al. 2004). This general preferred approach to dealing with uncertainty and ambiguity in a country also affects how business people and entrepreneurs perceive the effectiveness of rules and regulations. Individuals living in countries with high levels of uncertainty avoidance are more likely to view red tape as a necessary by‐product of regulation. In contrast, in low uncertainty avoidant countries ‘conflict and competition can be controlled within the rules of “fair play”’ (Mueller and Thomas 2000, p. 61). Hence, in low uncertainty avoidant countries, business people and entrepreneurs are likely to feel more constrained by rules and regulations, and thus experience more red tape. We hypothesize:
H6b: There will be a negative association between the level of uncertainty avoidance in a country and perceptions of red tape in the private sector.
3 METHODS
3.1 Data sources
Data on red tape and corruption are taken from the Executive Opinion Survey (EOS) of the World Economic Forum (WEF), which is part of its Global Competitiveness Report. Since 1979, the WEF sends out the EOS annually to capture the opinions of business leaders on a broad range of topics related to competitiveness that are not easily captured by official statistics (Browne et al. 2014). The EOS is available in more than 40 languages so as to prevent differences in proficiency in English (or any other major language) from influencing the results. Respondents include business executives from small and medium‐sized enterprises as well as large firms representing the main sectors of the economy (agriculture, manufacturing industry, non‐manufacturing industry, and services) (e.g., Chan and Cheung 2008). While the number of responses collected differs from one year to the next, about 12,000 executives from over 140 countries participate on average.1 The EOS produces aggregated measures of a country's business climate, including government efficiency, infrastructure, and competitiveness of economic performance (Knack 2007; Chan and Cheung 2008). As a result, the WEF only makes measures at the country level available. These country‐level measures are based on the simple arithmetic mean of the scores of the respondents from a certain country.
We merged the EOS data with a number of other data sources. We used World Bank data to capture a number of formal institutions and control variables. Our measure for political ideology is taken from the World Values Survey. The World Values Survey, which started in 1981, is a cross‐country project coordinated by the Institute for Social Research that gauges human beliefs and values in almost 100 countries. It consists of seven data waves to date and uses a standardized questionnaire to assemble information about demographics, self‐reported economic characteristics, and answers to specific questions about religion, political preferences, and attitudes. While detailed information per individual respondent is available per country per wave, we follow the same procedure as other cross‐country studies to arrive at average scores per country per year (e.g., Pevzner et al. 2015).
Cultural dimensions are taken from Hofstede (2001), which is one of the most common and frequently used frameworks for studying national culture (Chan and Cheung 2008; Taras et al. 2010). Hofstede's dimensions are based on data gathered between 1967 and 1973 in 20 languages from over 88,000 employees for a large multinational organization active in 72 countries. Country‐level factor analysis resulted in four dimensions of culture: power distance, individualism versus collectivism, uncertainty avoidance, and masculinity versus femininity. We also include data on federalism and type of legal system from two sources (Spamann 2008; Treisman 2008; see e.g., Fan et al. 2009 and Spamann 2010 for previous studies using these measures). Using among other sources the CIA Factbook, we verified whether the grouping into federal and unitary states remains representative for more recent years.
In sum, our dataset consists of six different sources, which enables us to address concerns about common source bias that are prevalent in public administration research (Jakobsen and Jensen 2015; see also Podsakoff et al. 2003) and answer calls for combining independent data sources when using survey measures (Favero and Bullock 2015). The sampling period starts in 2006 and ends in 2014.
3.2 Variables
Our dependent variable, Red tape, comes from the Executive Opinion Survey. Respondents were asked to respond to the following item on a 7‐point scale (with 1 indicating not burdensome at all, and 7 indicating extremely burdensome):2 ‘In your country, how burdensome is it for businesses to comply with governmental administrative requirements (e.g., permits, regulations, reporting)?’ This country‐level measure is only available as the simple arithmetic mean of the scores of executives from a certain country participating in the survey. With regard to our independent variables for formal institutions, Formalization is operationalized as the number of start‐up procedures to register a business, taken from the World Bank's Doing Business Project. This particular measure captures ‘the number of external parties, usually government‐related, that the entrepreneur faces before his new business is registered’ (Ho and Wong 2007, p. 192). Hence, a larger number of procedures indicates that more government agencies are involved in the process of registering a business, which implies in turn that the overall process is more formalized.3 Our formalization measure has been used in prior research to study the association between business regulatory quality and economic growth (Djankov et al. 2006), and the relationship between regulation and the formation rate of businesses (Van Stel et al. 2007). While this measure cannot account for intra‐country differences in the number of procedures required for starting a business, it does provide a consistent formalization measure that is appropriate for studying country‐level differences of this formal institution associated with red tape in the private sector.
The measure, Rule enforcement effectiveness, comes from the World Bank's Doing Business Project. This variable measures the number of calendar days required to enforce a contract from the filing of a lawsuit in court until the final determination of the lawsuit. The World Bank argues that the relative ease with which contractual obligations can be enforced through courts (e.g., in terms of the number of days required to enforce a contract) is an important indicator of the effectiveness of a country's legal institutions (Doing Business 2017). Djankov et al. (2008) and Nunn (2007) use this enforcement measure as an indicator of legal system and judicial quality in their comparative country‐level studies on debt enforcement efficiency and trade patterns. Federalism is a dummy variable that assumes a value of one if a country has a federal system in which entities, such as states or provinces, share power with a national government (e.g., the US, Germany and Spain) and zero otherwise (Treisman 2008).
To capture informal institutions, our independent variable Political ideology is taken from the World Values Survey and is based on an item that asked respondents to indicate on a 10‐point scale their views on the role of government, where 1 = ‘People should take more responsibility to provide for themselves’ and 10 = ‘Government should take more responsibility to ensure that everyone is provided for’; hence higher scores on this variable imply that, on average, people living in that country believe that the government should take more responsibility to ensure that everyone is provided for.4
The variable, Corruption, is an average score across five components of the EOS: ‘In your country, how common is it for firms to make undocumented extra payments or bribes in connection with (1) imports and exports; (2) public utilities; (3) annual tax payments; (4) awarding of public contracts and licences; (5) obtaining favourable judicial decisions?’ Response categories range from 1 = never occurs to 7 = very common.5
The cultural dimensions individualism and uncertainty avoidance are from Hofstede (2001). The variable, Individualism, captures ‘the degree to which people in a country prefer to act as individuals rather than as members of groups’ (Hofstede 1994, p. 6). A higher score on this dimension implies that a society is more individualistic. Uncertainty avoidance measures ‘the extent to which a society feels threatened by uncertain and ambiguous situations and tries to avoid these situations by providing greater career stability, establishing more formal rules, not tolerating deviant ideas and behaviors, and believing in absolute truths and the attainment of expertise’ (Hofstede 1980, p. 45). A higher score indicates a society that is more uncertainty avoidant. Crucially, in our study that encompasses nine years of data, the cultural measures do not change over time as various scholars in the cross‐cultural domain have argued that culture changes only very slowly (e.g., Minkov 2013). In line with existing research, we assume that these Hofstede scores accurately represent differences across countries in terms of individualism and uncertainty avoidance (e.g., Beugelsdijk et al. 2015; Eringa et al. 2015).
We also include a number of control variables that may be related to red tape in the private sector. Government size is operationalized as the general government final consumption expenditure as a percentage of GDP, taken from the World Bank database. The reasoning behind including this control variable is that a larger government may result in more red tape (Bozeman 1993; Bozeman and Feeney 2011). Drawing from Spamann (2008), we include a dummy variable, Common law, to control for the type of legal system. One mechanism by which type of legal system may affect red tape is through the level of procedural formalism, which is how the law regulates the operation of courts. Djankov et al. (2003, p. 453) find that procedural formalism is ‘systematically greater in civil than in common law countries, and is associated with higher expected duration of judicial proceedings, less consistency, less honesty, less fairness in judicial decisions, and more corruption’, which implies that red tape may also be more extensive in civil law systems.
Third, we control for economic growth as executives are likely to be less critical of government policies and, by extension, will perceive less red tape, if the economy is doing well. This variable is measured as the annual percentage growth rate of GDP at market prices based on constant local currency, obtained from the World Bank. Finally, in all our estimations we include year fixed effects (by including year dummies for 2007 to 2014) to control for possible differences in red tape between years. We winsorize each of the continuous variables at the top and bottom 1% to minimize the impact of extreme values.