In: Economics
Quantity |
Price |
Total |
Marginal |
Total |
Marginal |
Average |
0 |
25 |
0 |
25 |
30 |
— |
— |
2 |
24 |
48 |
23 |
35 |
2.5 |
17.5 |
4 |
23 |
92 |
21 |
45 |
5 |
11.25 |
6 |
22 |
132 |
19 |
60 |
7.5 |
10 |
8 |
21 |
168 |
17 |
77 |
8.5 |
9.63 |
10 |
20 |
200 |
15 |
100 |
11.5 |
10 |
12 |
19 |
228 |
13 |
126 |
13 |
10.5 |
14 |
18 |
252 |
11 |
165 |
19.5 |
11.79 |
16 |
17 |
272 |
9 |
210 |
22.5 |
13.13 |
18 |
16 |
288 |
7 |
260 |
25 |
14.44 |
20 |
15 |
300 |
5 |
320 |
30 |
16 |
a. The equilibrium condition of the monopolistic competitor is MC=MR. In the table given MC equals MR(Mc=(MC=$13, MR=$13) with the volume of output 12 and price $19. The optimum quantity of output is 12 and the optimum price is $19.
The profit of the firm is Total revenue− Total cost. At the equilibrium output the Total Revenue = $228 and Total cost = $126. Then the monopolistic competitor earns a total profit of $102. Per unit profit = Total profit/ units of sales which is equal to $102/12=$8.5.
In shortrun the supply is limited due to the barriers to the entry of new firms. Thus the monopolistic competitor is able to earn this extra normal profit in shortrun. But longrun new firms will enter into the industry and this will cause increased supply of output and price fall. This fall in price gives normal profit to all the firms in the industry in longrun.
b. The equilibrium condition of the perfect competitive market is also same as monopolistic competition ie MC=MR.