Question

In: Economics

Game theory: Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the winning bidder pays the average of the...

Game theory: Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the winning bidder pays the average of the two highest bids. Assume that players have valuations v1 > v2 > … > vn, that ties are won by the tied player with the highest valuation, and that each player’s valuation is common knowledge.

a. Is there any Nash equilibrium in which the two highest bids are different? If there is, give an example. If there is not, prove that no such equilibrium exists.

b. Is there any Nash equilibrium in which a player other than the one with the highest valuation wins? If there is, give an example. If there is not, prove that no such equilibrium exists.

c. Will bidding more than one’s own valuation be weakly dominated in this auction? Will bidding one’s own valuation exactly be weakly dominated? Will bidding less than one’s own valuation be weakly dominated?

d. What is the highest possible winning bid in any Nash equilibrium of this game? What is the lowest possible winning bid in Nash equilibrium?

Solutions

Expert Solution

a. In every Nash equilibrium a player with the highest valuation is the winner.

  • If bi > vi , then player’s i payoff is negative and it increases to 0 if he submits the bid equal to vi .
  • If maxji vj > bi , then player j such that vj > bi can win the object by submitting a bid in the open interval (bi , vj ), say vj. Then his payoff increases from 0 to .
  • If bi > maxji bj , then player i can increase his payoff by submitting a bid in the open interval (maxji bj , bi), say bi. Then his payoff increases from vi − bi to vi − bi + .

So if any of the conditions (i) − (iii) is violated, then b is not a Nash equilibrium.

b. Suppose that a vector of bids b satisfies (i)−(iii).

Player i is the winner and by (i) his payoff is non-negative.

His payoff can increase only if he bids less, but then by (iii) another player (the one who initially submitted the same bid as player i) becomes the winner,

while player’s i payoff becomes 0.

The payoff of any other player j is 0 and can increase only if he bids more and becomes the winner.

But then by (ii), maxjivj< bj , so his payoff becomes negative. So b is a Nash equilibrium.

c. Choose an arbitrary sequence of bids that for the clarity of the argument we denote by (vi , b−i). Suppose that i = argsmax (vi , b−i. We establish the following four claims.

But even after that each strategy bi ≠ vi is weakly dominated by vi , i.e., that vi is a weakly dominant strategy.

As an aside, recall that each weakly dominant strategy is unique, so we characterized bidding one’s valuation in the second-price auction in game theoretic terms.

d. If 2 players submit the same bid, and this bid is the highest, then the prize goes to the player with lower index,

e.g. if both player1 and player2 bid the same amount of money, the prize goes to player1. Players value the object differently, playeri valuation is vi, and v1>v2>⋯>vn.


Related Solutions

Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the winning bidder pays the average of the two highest...
Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the winning bidder pays the average of the two highest bids. As in the auction models considered in class, assume that players have valuations v1 > v2 > ... > vn, that ties are won by the tied player with the highest valuation, and that each player’s valuation is common knowledge. Is there any Nash equilibrium in which the two highest bids are different? If there is, give an example. If there is not,...
A second-price sealed-bid auction is an auction in which every bidder submits his or her bid...
A second-price sealed-bid auction is an auction in which every bidder submits his or her bid to the auctioneer, the auctioneer announces the winner to be the bidder who submits the highest bid, and the winner pays the highest bid among the losers. Is the following statement True, False, or Uncertain? Explain why. Every player has a weakly dominant strategy in second-price auction.
Suppose a single good is being sold in a sealed-bid auction (no bidder can observe the...
Suppose a single good is being sold in a sealed-bid auction (no bidder can observe the bids of other bidders). The rules of the auction are such that the person who bids the highest value for the good wins, but the winner only has to pay the value of the second-highest bid submitted. Assume that there are three people bidding for the good (?=1,2,3), and each values the good according to: ?1=$12 ?2=$16 ?3=$3 where ??v_i is the maximum willingness...
Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the seller draws one of the N bids at random....
Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the seller draws one of the N bids at random. The buyer whose bid was drawn wins the auction and pays the amount bid. Assume that buyer valuations follow a uniform(0,1) distribution. 1. What is the symmetric equilibrium bidding strategy b(v)? 2.What is the seller’s expected revenue? 3.Why doesn’t this auction pay the seller the same revenue as the four standard auctions? That is, why doesn’t the revenue equivalence theorem apply here? Be specific.
Second Price sealed bid-auction: Assume n players are bidding in an auction in order to obtain...
Second Price sealed bid-auction: Assume n players are bidding in an auction in order to obtain an indivisible object. Denote by vi the value player i attaches to the object; if she obtains the object at the price p her payoff is vi −p. Assume that the players’ valuations of the object are all different and all positive; number the players 1 through n in such a way that v1 > v2 > · · · > vn > 0....
Problem 1. An “antique” table is for sale in a sealed bid auction. It will go...
Problem 1. An “antique” table is for sale in a sealed bid auction. It will go to the high bidder at the price the high bidder bids. You don’t know if it is a fake or not, but you do know that 20% of all antiques that look like this one are fakes. You are not able to have an appraiser examine it. If it is a fake, you will know this after you buy it and it will be...
In auction​ bidding, the​ "winner's curse" is the phenomenon of the winning​ (or highest) bid price...
In auction​ bidding, the​ "winner's curse" is the phenomenon of the winning​ (or highest) bid price being above the expected value of the item being auctioned. A study was conducted to see if​less-experienced bidders were more likely to be impacted by the curse than​ super-experienced bidders. The study showed that of the 188 bids by​ super-experienced bidders, 25 winning bids were above the​ item's expected​ value, and of the bids by the 140 less-experienced bidders, 31 winning bids were above...
Consider 45 risk-neutral bidders who are participating in a second-price, sealed-bid auction. It is commonly known...
Consider 45 risk-neutral bidders who are participating in a second-price, sealed-bid auction. It is commonly known that bidders have independent private values. Based on this information, we know the optimal bidding strategy for each bidder is to: A. bid their own valuation of the item. B. shade their bid to just below their own valuation. C. bid according to the following bid function: b = v − (v − L)/n. D. bid one penny above their own valuation to ensure...
Consider a second-price sealed-bid auction. Suppose bidders' valuations are v1=10 and v2=10. Select all that apply....
Consider a second-price sealed-bid auction. Suppose bidders' valuations are v1=10 and v2=10. Select all that apply. (PLEASE EXPLAIN CHOICES COMPLETEY) a. One bidder submitting a bid equal to 10 and the other submitting a bid equal to 0 is a Nash equilibrium. b. Bidding a value b1 equal to her own valuation v1 is a weakly dominated strategy for bidder 1. c. Both bidders submitting bids equal to 0 is a Nash equilibrium. d. Both bidders submitting bids equal to...
a) Your company is bidding for a service contract in a first-price sealed-bid auction. You value...
a) Your company is bidding for a service contract in a first-price sealed-bid auction. You value the contract at $12 million. You believe the distribution of bids will be uniform, with a high value of $16 million and a low value of $3 million. What is your optimal strategy with 5 bidders? b) Your company is bidding for a service contract in a first-price sealed-bid auction. You value the contract at $12 million. You believe the distribution of bids will...
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT