Question

In: Economics

Consider a second-price sealed-bid auction. Suppose bidders' valuations are v1=10 and v2=10. Select all that apply....

Consider a second-price sealed-bid auction. Suppose bidders' valuations are v1=10 and v2=10. Select all that apply. (PLEASE EXPLAIN CHOICES COMPLETEY)

a.

One bidder submitting a bid equal to 10 and the other submitting a bid equal to 0 is a Nash equilibrium.

b.

Bidding a value b1 equal to her own valuation v1 is a weakly dominated strategy for bidder 1.

c.

Both bidders submitting bids equal to 0 is a Nash equilibrium.

d.

Both bidders submitting bids equal to 10 is a Nash equilibrium.

Solutions

Expert Solution

Firstly, to understand the solution the definition of Nash equilibrium has to be laid out clearly.

A nash equilibrium is a set of choices of each player such that there is no unilateral profitable deviation possible. That is no one player can be better off by choosing another bundle other than what is currently being chosen, given the other person's choice.

Now, let us consider each option.
Option A:One bidder submitting a bid equal to 10 and the other submitting a bid equal to 0 is a Nash equilibrium.

Let us consider two cases. First when player 1 choses to bid 10, and player 2 choses to bid 0. Second, when player 1 chooses to bid 0, and player 1 chooses to bid 10.

Case 1: When player 1 chooses to bid 10, and player 2 chooses to bid 0.
Player 1 gets the object, and receives a payoff of v1-b2=10-0=10.
Player 2 doesn't get the object, so the payoff is 0.

If player 1 chooses a higher bid, she will have the same payoff, so no profitable deviation there.
If player 1 chooses a lower bid than what she is currently bidding, but higher than player 2, still she will have the same payoff, so no profitable devitation there as well.
If player 1 chooses a lower bid than what she is currently bidding, and equal to player 2's bid, i.e. 0, then the prize is distributed equally, and her payoff is 5, which is less than her ealier payoff of 10, so she is worse off.
Therefore, player 1 does not have a profitable devitation.

If player 2 increases her bid, to 0<b2<10, she still doesn't get the object, so no profitable deviation.
If player 2 increases her bid, to b2=10, then she will get the half the prize and pay half the price, still no profitable devitation.
If player 2 increases her bid, to b2>10, then she will get the prize, but pay v1=10 for it, so essentially payoff is still zero.
Therefore, player 2 also does not have a profitable deviation
Therefore, Option A is correct.

Option B:Bidding a value b1 equal to her own valuation v1 is a weakly dominated strategy for bidder 1.

Let's take player 2's bid as given. So, there will be 3 cases.
1) b2<10.
Given player 2's bid. if player 1 bids b1=10, then he will make positive profit, if he bids b2<b1<10, then also +ve profit. If he bids b1<b2, then he doesn't get the object and makes 0 profit.
Therefore, we have proved that option B is incorrect. We need not investigate further.

Option C: Both bidders submitting bids equal to 0 is a Nash equilibrium.

If both bidders bid equal to 0, then any one can increase her bid and gain positive profit, since she still has to pay 0, and win the object.
Therefore, Option C is incorrect.

Option D: Both bidders submitting bids equal to 10 is a Nash equilibrium.

If for eg, player 1 deviates to a bid higher than 10, then still the payoff is 0, making her indifferent.
If her deviates to a bid lesser than 10, then she loses the object, and still has a payoff of 0.
So, there is no profitable deviation.

Option D is correct.


Related Solutions

Find a Nash Equilibrium of the second price sealed bid auction that is different from [v1,v2,v3,....,vn]
Find a Nash Equilibrium of the second price sealed bid auction that is different from [v1,v2,v3,....,vn]
Consider 45 risk-neutral bidders who are participating in a second-price, sealed-bid auction. It is commonly known...
Consider 45 risk-neutral bidders who are participating in a second-price, sealed-bid auction. It is commonly known that bidders have independent private values. Based on this information, we know the optimal bidding strategy for each bidder is to: A. bid their own valuation of the item. B. shade their bid to just below their own valuation. C. bid according to the following bid function: b = v − (v − L)/n. D. bid one penny above their own valuation to ensure...
Question 6. There are two bidders in a sealed-bid, second-price auction. The object for sale has...
Question 6. There are two bidders in a sealed-bid, second-price auction. The object for sale has a common value. Each bidder, i = 1,2, receives a signal i that is independently and uniformly distributed on the interval [0, 1]. The true value of the object, v, is the average of the two signals, v = (σ1 + σ2) / 2 (a) If bidder 1 gets the signal σ = 0.7, how much does he think the object is worth? (b)...
Consider a second price auction for a single item with two bidders. Suppose the bidders have...
Consider a second price auction for a single item with two bidders. Suppose the bidders have independent private values, uniformly drawn in the interval [0, 1]. Suppose the seller sets a reserve price p = 0.5; that is, only bids above p = 0.5 can win. If a bidder bids above p and the other bids below p, then the first bidder wins and pays a price p. If both bid above p, then the highest bidder wins and pays...
A second-price sealed-bid auction is an auction in which every bidder submits his or her bid...
A second-price sealed-bid auction is an auction in which every bidder submits his or her bid to the auctioneer, the auctioneer announces the winner to be the bidder who submits the highest bid, and the winner pays the highest bid among the losers. Is the following statement True, False, or Uncertain? Explain why. Every player has a weakly dominant strategy in second-price auction.
Second Price sealed bid-auction: Assume n players are bidding in an auction in order to obtain...
Second Price sealed bid-auction: Assume n players are bidding in an auction in order to obtain an indivisible object. Denote by vi the value player i attaches to the object; if she obtains the object at the price p her payoff is vi −p. Assume that the players’ valuations of the object are all different and all positive; number the players 1 through n in such a way that v1 > v2 > · · · > vn > 0....
Consider a private value auction with 2 bidders. The auction is carried out as a second...
Consider a private value auction with 2 bidders. The auction is carried out as a second price sealed bid auction where in case of a tie between the bidders, the winner is selected by a coin toss. The seller has valuation of the good of zero and will accept any bid at or greater than zero. Each bidder knows his/her own valuation, v, and does not know the valuation of the other bidder. It is common knowledge that the bidder...
Consider a second price auction with 2 bidders, 1 and 2, who have values for the...
Consider a second price auction with 2 bidders, 1 and 2, who have values for the good of 20 and 80, respectively. Each knows what the other bidder’s valuation is so there is no uncertainty. (a) Show that choosing a bid equal to one’s valuation is a weakly dominant strategy for bidder 1. (b) Show that if each bidder plays a weakly dominant strategy, the bidder with the highest value always wins the good (c) Is it a Nash equilibrium...
Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the winning bidder pays the average of the two highest...
Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the winning bidder pays the average of the two highest bids. As in the auction models considered in class, assume that players have valuations v1 > v2 > ... > vn, that ties are won by the tied player with the highest valuation, and that each player’s valuation is common knowledge. Is there any Nash equilibrium in which the two highest bids are different? If there is, give an example. If there is not,...
Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the seller draws one of the N bids at random....
Consider a sealed-bid auction in which the seller draws one of the N bids at random. The buyer whose bid was drawn wins the auction and pays the amount bid. Assume that buyer valuations follow a uniform(0,1) distribution. 1. What is the symmetric equilibrium bidding strategy b(v)? 2.What is the seller’s expected revenue? 3.Why doesn’t this auction pay the seller the same revenue as the four standard auctions? That is, why doesn’t the revenue equivalence theorem apply here? Be specific.
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT