In: Economics
Demand for hotel rooms in Tallahassee takes two possible values: on game days, demand is described by the demand curve q = 100−p, while on non-game-days demand is described by the demand curve q = 60 − 2p.
(a) Suppose that the hotel price on game days is ph = 80. What quantity is demanded at this price?
(b) Find the inverse demand curve on non-game-days. Assuming that the price on game days is ph = 80 as above, what price would induce the same quantity demanded on non-game-days as on game days?
(c) Plot the demand curves on game days and on non-game-days. Pay careful attention to the price and quantity intercepts for both curves.
(d) Assuming the price on non-game-days is as you found in (ii), what is consumer surplus in this market on non-game-days? What is consumer surplus on game days?
(e) Suppose that you encounter the following claim: “Because the hotel price is higher on game days than on non-game-days, consumer surplus in the hotel market must be lower on game days.” What is wrong with this claim?
(a) On Game Days:
The hotel price ph = 80
Demand is described by the demand curve q = 100−p
The quantity that is demanded at this price is q = 100 - 80 = 20 units
The quantity demanded is found out by putting the value of price ph in the demand function.
(b) On Non Game Days:
Demand is described by the demand curve q = 60 − 2p.
So, the inverse demand curve on non-game-days is found out by solving for price
q = 60 − 2p,
2p = 60 - q
p = 30 - q/2
Assuming that the price on game days is ph = 80 as above, the price that would induce the same quantity demanded on non-game-days as on game days is:
When the price is ph 80 on game days, the quantity demanded is 20 units. So, for 20 units to be demanded on non-game days, we put this quantity in the demand function and solve for the price.
Demand curve for non game days q = 60 − 2p
20 = 60 - 2p
2p = 60 - 20
p = 40/2 = ph 20
(c) The demand curves on game days can be plotted from the demand function
The demand function is: q = 100−p
Price | Quantity |
100 | 0 |
90 | 10 |
80 | 20 |
70 | 30 |
60 | 40 |
50 | 50 |
40 | 60 |
30 | 70 |
20 | 80 |
10 | 90 |
0 | 100 |
We find these quantities by substituting price in the demand function above. Plotting these points on a graph:
The demand curves on non game days can be plotted from the demand function
The demand function is: q = 60 − 2p
Price | Quantity |
30 | 0 |
20 | 20 |
10 | 40 |
0 | 60 |
We find these quantities by substituting price in the demand function above. Plotting these points on a graph:
(d) The consumer surplus in this market on non-game-days when the price is 20 is shown by the area of the red triangle in the graph:
Consumer Surplus = 1/2 * Base * Height
= 1/2 * 20 * (30-20)
=1/2 * 20 * 10
= 100
The consumer surplus in this market on game-days when the price is 20 is shown by the area of the red triangle in the graph:
Consumer Surplus = 1/2 * Base * Height
= 1/2 * 80 * (100-20)
=1/2 * 80 * 80
= 3200
(e) The following claim: “Because the hotel price is higher on game days than on non-game-days, consumer surplus in the hotel market must be lower on game days.” is not correct because the demand function for both game and non-game days is different. The quantity demanded for hotel price on game days is higher than the quantity demanded for hotel-price on non-game days. For example, on non game days, atprice 30, the quantity demanded is 0 whereas on game days, at price 30, the quantity demanded is 70 so the consumer surplus would also be different.