In: Economics
t/f/u why?
comparative advantage allows for improved economic and social conditions as a result of
immigration in a domestic economy.
Draw a diagram/table showing improvements/digressions
as a result of comparative advantage and immigration.
Immigration policy involves fundamental issues about what and who we are as a
country. There are no simple answers on immigration policy because different people
can legitimately assign different weights to the welfare of new immigrants, recent
immigrants, and various groups of natives. In addition, there is considerable debate and
disagreement among economists about the economic impacts of immigration.
The Comprehensive Immigration Reform Act of 2006 that was reported out of the
Senate Judiciary Committee last week seems to represent a reasonable compromise in
view of the competing interests of different stakeholders. Two important economic
issues have been overlooked in this debate, however. First, confident predictions that
immigrant inflows have depressed the wages and employment opportunities of U.S.
workers, particularly of the less skilled, belie an unsettled and often unsupportive
research base. The best available evidence does not support the view that large waves of
immigrants in the past have had a detrimental effect on the labor market opportunities of
natives, including the less skilled and minorities. Any claim that increased immigration
resulting from the Senate Judiciary Committee’s bill will necessarily reduce the wages of
incumbent workers should be viewed as speculation with little solid research support.
Second, a guest worker program that does not permit free mobility by foreign workers
admitted to the U.S. carries significant risks to the U.S. economy. Job shopping is an
essential protection against exploitation and inefficient allocation of resources. Limiting
the mobility of guest workers would be a step backward for the U.S. economy. Each of
these points is elaborated on below.
None of these comments are meant to deny the fact that problems faced by low-
skilled workers in the labor market are serious, or to argue that public policy should not
address the problems of less skilled workers. Real earnings for those at the bottom of the
income distribution have been stagnant or falling for a generation. There are many
policies that would be helpful for less skilled workers that deserve consideration, such as
an expansion of the Earned Income Tax Credit, an increase in the child tax credit, a boost
in the minimum wage, and increased job training. Stricter immigration policy, however,
is unlikely to materially affect the earnings or job prospects of less skilled workers.
Effect of Immigration on Natives’ Wages and Job Opportunities
● One of the clearest and most compelling studies of the effect of immigration on
natives’ labor market opportunities was conducted by David Card of the University of California at Berkeley and published in Industrial & Labor Relations Review in 1990.
Specifically, Professor Card examined the effect of the Mariel Boatlift — which resulted
in 125,000 new Cuban immigrants arriving in southern Florida between May and
September of 1980 — on the labor market in Miami. This sudden and unexpected wave
of immigration increased the city’s labor force by 7 percent. Most of the new workers
were unskilled. Yet Professor Card found that the wages and employment opportunities
of unskilled workers who already lived in Miami were not hurt by this large inflow of
immigrants. “Even among the Cuban population,” he concluded, “wages and
unemployment rates of earlier immigrants were not substantially affected by the arrival of
the Mariels.” He reached his conclusions by comparing Miami with other cities that were
not affected by the Mariel Boatlift. This study, which is a model for research, was
specifically mentioned in Professor Card’s citation when he was awarded the Clark
Medal, a prize given by the American Economic Association every other year.
● The central finding of David Card’s study of the Mariel Boatlift — that an
unanticipated influx of immigrants does not have a harmful effect on the employment or
wages of natives — has been replicated in other settings by other researchers. For
example, Professor Jennifer Hunt of McGill University found similar results in a study of
the impact on the French labor market of 900,000 people who were repatriated from
Algeria in 1962. In addition, Rachel Friedberg of Brown University found that a large
inflow of Russian immigrants into Israel after emigration restrictions in the Soviet Union
were lifted, which resulted in a 12 percent jump in Israel’s population, did not have a
harmful effect on the labor market outcomes of other Israelis.
● Another line of research uses cross-city data to examine how natives’ job market
outcomes vary with the share of the workforce in the city contributed by immigrants.
This line of research finds mixed results, but is arguably less compelling than studies that
focus on large influxes of immigrants to a particular labor because immigrants choose the
city in which they settle, and economic conditions in the city are probably an important
factor in that decision. By contrast, studies that focus on the natural experiment created
by a sudden and unanticipated influx of immigrants to a specific country or labor market
have the advantage of analyzing an event in which immigrants entered a labor market for
reasons largely beyond their control and unrelated to the state of the economy in the labor
market where they sought work. In addition, because these natural experiments are often
large relative to the size of the labor market, it is hard to argue that any effect of
immigration was offset by an outflow of other residents.
● Studies that claim to find a deleterious effect of immigration on natives’ wages are
typically based on theoretical predictions, not actual experience. These theoretical
predictions are very sensitive to their underlying assumptions, which are often
controversial. Existing theoretical predictions typically do not factor in relevant
consequences of immigration, such as an increase in demand for goods and services
produced in the U.S. that results from greater demand due to immigrants.
● Why does immigration apparently have such a benign effect on natives’ wages and
employment opportunities? The answer to this question is not clear, but it is probably
more complicated than the simple response that immigrants take jobs that U.S. workers
do not want. One likely factor is that, in addition to increasing the supply of labor,
immigrants increase the demand for goods and services produced in the U.S. This leads
to higher wages and employment for all workers in the U.S. Immigration can also result
in an increase in capital investment. And many immigrants become entrepreneurs,
creating jobs for other immigrants and natives. Immigrant entrepreneurs may be
particularly likely to develop export opportunities for American products given their
connections abroad and language skills.
Guest Workers (H-2c Nonimmigrant Visas) and the Labor Market
● Economic efficiency requires that all workers in the U.S. labor market are treated on a
level playing field. This means that the same set of legal protections apply to all workers.
The notion of employment at will, or the ability of employers to dismiss workers at will
and the ability of employees to leave a job for a better opportunity or for any other
reason, is a hallmark of the U.S. labor market. Free mobility of labor is a bulwark against
exploitation. Workers who feel mistreated can leave their job to search for another one or
exit the labor force. Free mobility is also economically efficient. Workers move to the
opportunities that value their services most highly. If guest workers do not have the
opportunity to change jobs with minimal administrative burden, other workers in the U.S.
will potentially suffer because employers will have some scope to exploit guest workers
and lower labor conditions more generally.
● It is important that guest workers are paid wages and fringe benefits that meet the
market level and that they are afforded all of the protections under the labor laws that are
available to other workers in their position. If not, then the guest worker program will
favor industries that hire guest workers over other industries. This type of industrial
policy would result in an inefficient allocation of resources. To ensure that workers are
paid appropriately and afforded adequate protections is to allow them to change jobs if
they so choose.
● The President has proposed that immigration reform include a guest worker program.
The Senate Judiciary Committee bill allows up to 400,000 nonimmigrant workers to enter
the U.S. each year. This is the equivalent of 38 percent of annual job growth in the last
four years. The provisions of the Senate Judiciary Committee bill call for the temporary
visa to expire if the guest worker is unemployed for 60 or more days. The median
duration of an unemployment spell in the U.S. currently is 9.6 weeks. Workers can
become unemployed for reasons completely unrelated to their job performance; for
example, their plant could close. The 60-day restriction could prove to be burdensome
for many temporary workers, causing them to quickly find work that is not well suited for
their talents or return home. Workers who qualify for Unemployment Insurance are
usually eligible for 26 weeks or more of unemployment benefits. Guest workers will
presumably pay UI taxes, yet they would not be able to receive more than 60 days of
benefits. Treating guest workers differently than other workers will result in an uneven
playing field.
● If the only route to citizenship for temporary and immigrant workers is for employers
to sponsor them for citizenship after a period of years, then it is inevitable that employers
will hold an advantage over temporary and immigrant workers that they do not hold over
other workers. This advantage could lead to exploitation that would hurt both foreign
workers and domestic workers. One partial solution to this concern is to allow others
besides employers to sponsor immigrant and nonimmigrant workers for a Green Card and
for citizenship, such as religious organizations, nonprofit volunteer organizations, and
community groups. Reducing the scope for employers to exploit immigrant and
nonimmigrant guest workers will help protect domestic workers by preventing a race to
the bottom.
● The experience with H1-B visas has been that enforcement is inadequate to ensure that
all workers are paid what they are promised or paid the prevailing wage. Regulation is
unlikely to provide adequate protection for nonimmigrant workers unless they are free to
move between jobs with minimal administrative burden and unless they can spend
adequate periods of time searching for work should they become unemployed.
● Past experience has been that a great many of those admitted as “short-term” guest
workers eventually stay. One concern, however, is that because of their temporary
horizons the guest workers fail to acculturate and invest in human capital.
● The guest worker visas, if they are included in the Act, should be available for the
largest number of industries and occupations possible to avoid favoring certain industries
and occupations. Historically, large guest worker programs were only started during
emergencies. The U.S. currently faces, and is forecasted to face, more intense labor
shortages for skilled workers than for unskilled workers. Guest worker visas should not
be limited to agriculture and other industries that intensively use unskilled workers. The
best way to allocate H-2c visas would be to have employers pay a fee that is determined
in an open auction in order to bring a worker in the U.S. under an H-2c visa. Once the
workers are in the U.S., they should be allowed to move between jobs without risk.