In: Economics
Question 1.
Use one example to explain how bad institutions and policies can raise the cost of investments. (10 marks)
Cross-country empirical analyses, in combination with
micro-level studies, provide strong support for the overwhelming
importance of institutions in predicting the level of development
in countries around the world (Hall and Jones, 1999; Acemoglu,
Johnson and Robinson, 2001). Protection of property rights,
effective law enforcement, and efficient bureaucracies, together
with a broad range of norms and civic mores, are found to be
strongly correlated to better economic performance over time. This
essay aims to explain why institutions are important to economic
development and to provide evidence for the arguments made. It
argues that institutions support economic development through four
broad channels: determining the costs of economic transactions,
determining the degree of appropriability of return to investment,
determining the level for oppression and expropriation, and
determining the degree to which the environment is conducive to
cooperation and increased social capital. Evidence is derived from
the literature, from comparison of countries, and from examples at
the micro level.Institutions conducive to economic development
reduce the costs of economic activity. The costs include
transaction costs such as search and information costs, bargaining
and decision costs, policing and enforcement costs (Coase, 1992, p
197; Dahlman, 1979, p. 149). They lower transaction costs by
providing common legal frameworks (e.g. contracts and contract
enforcement, commercial norms and rules), and they encourage trust
by providing policing and justice systems for the adherence to
common laws and regulations. Communities in LDCs typically rely on
kinship or ethnic and religious ties for trade. Norms and networks
of common language and religion may be enough to ensure compliance
with agreements on economic exchange; collective punishment and
social reputation may be enough to ensure the enforcement of (often
informal) contracts even in the absence of a third party. Greif
(1993) describes the trade networks of Maghribi traders which
permitted the sharing of information on dishonest traders and their
collective punishment. To take advantage of opportunities for trade
with different groups and increase the size of economic
transactions, however, cultural ties are not enough. There is need
for greater information about trading partners, and for
institutions which ensure agreements on the details of exchange and
compliance to the agreed conditions. These take the form of
contracts, codes of conduct, standardized weights and measures,
disclosure agreements, and enforcement through courts and policing.
Where transaction costs are small, the private enforcement of
contracts may still be preferred. But as economic relations develop
and become increasingly impersonal, the role of a third party to
enforce compliance to rules is increasingly necessary . Growth can
generate virtuous circles of prosperity and opportunity. Strong
growth and
employment opportunities improve incentives for parents to invest
in their children’s
education by sending them to school. This may lead to the emergence
of a strong and
growing group of entrepreneurs, which should generate pressure for
improved
governance. Strong economic growth therefore advances human
development, which, in turn, promotes economic growth.
But under different conditions, similar rates of growth can have
very different effects on
poverty, the employment prospects of the poor and broader
indicators of human
development. The extent to which growth reduces poverty depends on
the degree to
which the poor participate in the growth process and share in its
proceeds. Thus, both
the pace and pattern of growth matter for reducing poverty.
A successful strategy of poverty reduction must have at its core
measures to promote
rapid and sustained economic growth. The challenge for policy is to
combine growthpromoting policies with policies that allow the poor
to participate fully in the
opportunities unleashed and so contribute to that growth. This
includes policies to make
labour markets work better, remove gender inequalities and increase
financial inclusion.
Asian countries are increasingly tackling this agenda of ‘inclusive
growth’. India’s most
recent development plan has two main objectives: raising economic
growth and making
growth more inclusive, policy mirrored elsewhere in South Asia and
Africa.
Future growth will need to be based on an increasingly globalised
world that offers new
opportunities but also new challenges. New technologies offer not
only ‘catch-up’
potential but also ‘leapfrogging’ possibilities. New science offers
better prospects
across both productive and service sectors.
Future growth will also need to be environmentally sustainable.
Improved management of water and other natural resources is
required, together with movement towards low carbon technologies by
both developed and developing countries. With the proper
institutions, growth and environmental sustainability may be seen a
complements, not
substitutes. DFID will work for inclusive growth through a number
of programmes and continues to spend heavily on health and
education, which have a major impact on poor people’s
ability to take part in growth opportunities.
More and better research on the drivers of growth will be needed to
improve policy. But
ultimately the biggest determinants of growth in a country will be
its leadership, policies
and institutions. Economic diversification remains a challenge for
most developing countries and is arguably greatest for countries
with the lowest incomes as well as for those whose economies are
small, landlocked and/or dominated by primary commodity dependence.
For such countries, economic diversification is inextricably linked
with the structural transformation of their economies and the
achievement of higher levels of productivity resulting from the
movement of economic resources within and between economic sectors.
Rooted in examples of World Bank Group support, this chapter traces
the boundaries of any discussion of economic diversification by
advancing a definition that encompasses two related dimensions of
diversification: (i) trade diversification (i.e. exporting new or
better products, or to new markets) and (ii) domestic production
diversification (i.e. cross-sectoral rebalancing of output, driving
the reallocation of resources across industries and within
industries between firms to increase total factor productivity).
The chapter raises awareness on the complexity of the
diversification process and the state of knowledge surrounding
economic diversification. While the current global environment
creates challenges for poor, small, landlocked and/or
resource-dependent countries, a range of new diversification routes
can be followed. This however requires that policy attention be
paid to four key determinants of successful diversification
strategies, which development partners and International
Organisations can support through targeted Aid for Trade
interventions. These are: (i) the supply of appropriate incentive
frameworks; (ii) investments and policy reforms targeted at
reducing trade costs; (iii) effective policies to support
adjustment and the reallocation of resources towards new
activities; and (iv) government interventions directed at specific
market, policy and institutional failures. The first scenario in
the study looked at how much progress
each of these countries could make toward the MDGs by 2015 without
significant increases in aid flows or improvements in policies.
(The projected outcomes under this scenario and the second scenario
with improved policies and
higher aid, described below, reflect the judgments of World Bank
country teams, supported by existing analysis.) The left panel of
Chart 1 provides a summary of the prospects for the 18 countries
under the first scenario. More countries are likely to attain the
education and poverty goals than those for health or the
environment. In general, this is representative of what can be
expected if the countries continue to pursue policies aimed at
maintaining macroeconomic stability
and promoting structural reform. The growth payoff from these
policies will yield the biggest gains in reducing income poverty
and increasing primary school enrollment. However, even among the
education goals, while the primary school enrollment target is
expected to be met in almost two-thirds of the sample countries,
those for primary school completion and gender equality pose bigger
challenges. Similarly, while almost half the sample countries would
meet the income poverty goal, several of them will not be able to
meet the goal of reducing hunger. The child and maternal mortality
goals are projected to remain unmet almost universally in the
sample .Only Bangladesh, Indonesia, and Vietnam are likely to meet
the child mortality goal. And on maternal mortality, probably only
Vietnam will meet the MDG. Reaching these goals is made more
difficult in many of the sub-Saharan countries in the sample
because of the spread of the HIV/AIDS epidemic in the 1990s.How
would significantly better policies and more aid interact in
stepping up the pace of these countries’ progress toward
the MDGs. The outcomes for each country under this second scenario
are summarized in the right panel of which shows how powerful this
combination could be. For example, it would probably allow all 18
sample countries to achieve the poverty goals, and several of them,
including Mozambique,Uganda, and Vietnam, could make even sharper
reductions in poverty than called for by the MDGs. Significant
progress could also be expected on the education goals, with almost
two-thirds of the sample countries attaining the targets even for
primary school completion and gender equality. However, progress on
the health and environmental goals would remain a challenge . Only
a third or fewer of the countries would achieve all the targets in
either area, and some would not meet any of the goals. For
improvements to occur at this faster pace, substantial policy and
institutional reforms will be necessary to accelerate growth and
improve service delivery. The needed reforms fall into three broad
areas: improving the environment for private sector activity,
particularly in terms of the rule of law and infrastructure;
enhancing the quality of governance and capacity in the public
sector; and delivering more effective human development and other
basic services to poor people.