Question

In: Economics

A seller wishes to auction a single unit of an indivisible object. She can do so...

A seller wishes to auction a single unit of an indivisible object. She can do so in one of the following two ways (i) through a first-price auction to n bidders, (ii) through a second-price auction with optimally chosen reserve price to n - 1 bidders. Each bidder's valuation is private information and is an independent draw from the uniform distribution on [0, 1]. The seller values the object at 0.

(a) Which of the two alternatives would you recommend to the seller?

(b) Show that for a large number of bidders, the seller would be indifferent between the two alternatives.

Solutions

Expert Solution

The seller can prefer the first option because the indivisible object can be sell by n bid auction.

• A single indivisible object is for sale.

• There is a fixed number n of bidders i = 1, . . . , n. •

The bidders submit sealed bids. So bids are simultaneous and independent. The bid of bidder i is denoted bi .

• Each bidder i has a valuation for the object, denoted by vi . He enjoys vi if and only if he wins the object.

• The highest bidder wins the object. If there are two or more bids tied at the top, the winner is chosen randomly. All top bidders win with positive probability.

• The price paid depends on whether we are in a secondprice or a first-price auction.

Only the winning bidder pays. The price paid for the object is denoted by p.

• Bidders are risk-neutral. If i wins the object and the price is p, his utility is vi ? p. All non-winners have a utility of 0. If there is uncertainty about who wins, expected payoffs guide the bidders’ behavior.

Second-Price, Known Valuations

• Typically, each bidder will know his own vi and not observe the valuations of other bidders. But to begin with we look at the case in which all bidders know the valuations of all other bidders as well.

• This simplifies things and will be useful later when we look at the case in which i does not observe the other bidders’ valuations.

• Fix (v1, . . . , vn), known to all. The only thing that matters for i in deciding how much to bid is the largest bid of all other bidders. This is because if he wins (becausehis bid is highest), this bid will be the price he pays. • For each i, let mi be the largest bid among all bidders but i.

That is mi = max   {bj}

• Remember, bids are simultaneous and independent. So, given any possible configuration of the bids of others, how should i set bi? We can proceed on a case-by-case basis as follows.

1. Suppose mi > vi.

(a) Bidding bi ? vi makes i lose the auction. He gets a payoff of zero.

(b) Bidding vi < bi < mi makes i lose the auction. He gets a payoff of zero.

(c) Bidding bi = mi makes i’s bid tied as the top bid with one or more other bids. So i wins with positive probability, and pays a price p = mi . If he wins he gets vi ? p < 0. If he does not win he gets zero. So, in this case, his expected payoff is negative.

(d) Bidding bi > mi makes i win the auction for sure. So, in this case he gets vi ? p = vi ? mi < 0.

• From cases (1a) through (1d) we can conclude that if mi > vi , then there is no choice of bi that is better than setting bi = vi . Some other choices are just as good for bidder i, but no choice is better.

2. Suppose mi = vi .

(a) Bidding bi < vi makes i lose the auction. He gets a payoff of zero.

(b) Bidding bi = vi makes i’s bid tied as the top bid with one or more other bids. So i wins with positive probability, and pays a price p = mi = vi . If he wins he gets vi ? p = 0. If he does not win he gets zero. So, in this case, his expected payoff is zero.

(c) Bidding bi > vi makes i win the auction for sure. His payoff is vi ? p. Since p = mi = vi , his payoff is zero.

• From cases (2a) through (2c) we can conclude that if mi = vi , then there is no choice of bi that is better than setting bi = vi . Bidder i gets a payoff of zero, regardless of his bid bi .

3. Suppose mi < vi .

(a) Bidding bi < mi makes i lose the auction. He gets a payoff of zero.

(b) Bidding bi = mi makes i’s bid tied as the top bid with one or more other bids. So i wins with positive probability, and pays a price p = mi . If he wins he gets vi ? mi > 0. If he does not win he gets zero. So, in this case, his expected payoff positive but below vi ? mi .

(c) Bidding mi < bi < vi makes i win the auction for sure. His payoff is vi ? p. Since p = mi , his payoff is vi ? mi > 0.

(d) Bidding bi = vi makes i win the auction for sure. His payoff is vi ? p. Since p = mi , his payoff is vi ? mi > 0.

(e) Bidding bi > vi makes i win the auction for sure. His payoff is vi ? p. Since p = mi , his payoff is vi ? mi > 0.

• From cases (3a) through (3e) we can conclude that if mi < vi , then there is no choice of bi that is better than setting bi = vi . Some other choices are just as good for bidder i, but no choice is better.

• Putting together all the cases, (1a) through (3e) we can conclude that, regardless of mi , there is no choice of bi that is better for i than setting bi = vi . Depending on mi , some choices may be worse. But no choice is ever better.

• Another way to say this is that bidding bi = vi weakly dominates all other strategies.

• Remember that it is okay to rule out weakly dominated strategies (not okay in general to do this iteratively). They are not robust to the possibility of “mistakes.”

• Also, we know that after deleting weakly dominated strategies, at least one Nash equilibrium will still be there.

• Hence we can conclude that the unique Nash equilibrium not involving weakly dominated strategies is for each bidder i to bid bi = vi .

• Notice one appealing property of the Nash equilibrium we have found. The bidder with the largest vi wins the auction (if there are two or more valuations tied at the top, then one of the top valuers wins for sure).

• An auction with the property that (one of) the highest valuers wins the object is called an efficient auction.


Related Solutions

Consider a two-person problem in which there is a single seller who owns an indivisible object and single potential buyer of the object Each agent has a value for the object that is known to him but not known to the other agent.
Consider a two-person problem in which there is a single seller who owns an indivisible object and single potential buyer of the object Each agent has a value for the object that is known to him but not known to the other agent. The mechanism for (possible) trade is that each agent announces a price, and if the buyer's announcement is larger than the seller's announcement, the object is sold to the buyer at the seller's announced price. There is...
“… the problem is which of two people should have an indivisible object, a “seller”(which originally...
“… the problem is which of two people should have an indivisible object, a “seller”(which originally has it) or a “buyer”. The efficient solution is that whoever values it more should have it, perhaps with some payment to the other.” (J. Farrell, Economics Perspectives, 1987, p. 120). Discuss all different types of auctions explaining which of these ensure that the principle in the above statement applies, why it leads to a Pareto efficient outcome and whether such a type of...
Two buyers bid in an auction for a single object. Each can bid any integer amount...
Two buyers bid in an auction for a single object. Each can bid any integer amount from $0 to $10. The two bids are made simultaneously and independently of each other. The buyers’ respective values are v1 = 5 and v2 = 10. The bidder with the higher bid wins (obtains the object) and pays the amount of his own bid. However, the bidder who does not win the auction and thus does not get the object is also obliged...
Two buyers bid in an auction for a single object. Each can bid any integer amount...
Two buyers bid in an auction for a single object. Each can bid any integer amount from $0 to $10. The two bids are made simultaneously and independently of each other. The buyers’ respective values are v1 = 5 and v2 = 10. The bidder with the higher bid wins (obtains the object) and pays the amount of his own bid. However, the bidder who does not win the auction and thus does not get the object is also obliged...
Consider a seller who wants to sell a single unit of a good and a group...
Consider a seller who wants to sell a single unit of a good and a group of firms interested in buying the good. The seller decides to run a sealed-bid, second-price auction. Your firm intends to bid in the auction and had a private value of c for the good being sold, but is unsure of the number of other firms bidding. There will be either two or three additional firms bidding in the auction, each with an independent private...
Suppose a single good is being sold in a sealed-bid auction (no bidder can observe the...
Suppose a single good is being sold in a sealed-bid auction (no bidder can observe the bids of other bidders). The rules of the auction are such that the person who bids the highest value for the good wins, but the winner only has to pay the value of the second-highest bid submitted. Assume that there are three people bidding for the good (?=1,2,3), and each values the good according to: ?1=$12 ?2=$16 ?3=$3 where ??v_i is the maximum willingness...
What are the buyer's remedies when the seller delivers nonconforming goods? What can the seller do...
What are the buyer's remedies when the seller delivers nonconforming goods? What can the seller do to preserve the contract?
1. Arsema is in her late twenties. She is still single so her consumption behavior is...
1. Arsema is in her late twenties. She is still single so her consumption behavior is different from that of her same-aged friends who have already married and had children. This suggests that ___________________________________. family life cycle is a useful segmentation variable for many types of products segmenting a marketing isn't always helpful for marketers marketers should focus on one variable when performing a segmentation analysis psychographic variables are always the best segmentation variable age and gender always leads to...
Juanita is getting ready to do her taxes. She is single and lives in San Francisco.
2. Taxes paid for a given income levelJuanita is getting ready to do her taxes. She is single and lives in San Francisco. Juanita earned $100,000 in taxable income in 2015. She reviews the following table, which shows the IRS tax rates for a single taxpayer in 2015.On Annual Taxable Income...The Tax Rate Is...(Percent)Up to $9,22510.0From $9,225 to $37,45015.0From $37,450 to $90,75025.0From $90,750 to $189,30028.0From $189,300 to $411,50033.0From $411,500 to $413,20035.0Over $413,20039.6Based on the IRS table, Juanita calculates that her...
Article: Teacher and single mother can retire at 55 with room to spare, if she plays...
Article: Teacher and single mother can retire at 55 with room to spare, if she plays her cards right. As noted in the article, Brooke does not currently have a TFSA. Assume you are financial advisors. Brooke recently learned about the benefits of a TFSA, and she has asked to meet with you to get your recommendation on what steps she can do to improve her financial situation in retirement. Outline your recommendations and support them using explanations and show...
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT