Question

In: Economics

In looking at Real World Fiscal Policy, one might want to consider the timing, or lag,...

  1. In looking at Real World Fiscal Policy, one might want to consider the timing, or lag, or speed at which a policy can go into effect. How do the Tax cuts of 2001,2003, and the 2020 policies stack up when looking at timing issues?

Solutions

Expert Solution

The biggest tax policy changes enacted under President George W. Bush were the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts, often referred to as the “Bush tax cuts” but formally named the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA) and the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA). High-income taxpayers benefitted most from these tax cuts, with the top 1 percent of households receiving an average tax cut of over $570,000 between 2004-2012. Despite promises from proponents of the tax cuts, evidence suggests that they did not improve economic growth or pay for themselves, but instead ballooned deficits and debt and contributed to a rise in income inequality.

The 2001,2003 and 2020 tax cuts reduced the top four marginal income tax rates (see Table 1), as well as the tax rate on capital gains and dividends. Reducing the top marginal tax rates (the tax on each additional dollar of income above a threshold) reduced the average tax rate (total tax liability as a share of total income) for all taxpayers with incomes above those thresholds.

Income Tax Rate Reductions Under the 2001 and 2003 Tax Cuts
Taxable Incomea Previous Rate New Rate
Below $17,000 15% 10%
$17,000 — $68,000 15% 15%
$68,000 — $137,000 28% 25%
$137,000 — $209,000 31% 28%
$209,000 — $374,000 36% 33%
Above $374,000 39.6% 35%

The cost of the tax laws enacted during George W. Bush’s administration is equal to roughly 2 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in 2010, the year the provisions were fully phased in.This figure includes the amount the tax cuts increased the cost of “patching” the Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT) to keep the tax from affecting millions of upper-middle-class households, a problem the tax cuts helped to cause.

At the time, many policymakers — including President Bush and Federal Reserve Chair Alan Greenspan — cited projected surpluses and falling debt as a reason to cut taxes. But as the nation’s fiscal outlook changed, because the tax cuts were financed by borrowing, they added to a growing national debt.

The 2 percent of GDP cost figure does not include the extra interest costs resulting from the required borrowing. In 2013 CBPP estimated that, when the associated interest costs are taken into account, the Bush tax cuts (including those that policymakers made permanent) would add $5.6 trillion to deficits from 2001 to 2018. This means that the Bush tax cuts will be responsible for roughly one-third of the federal debt owed by 2018.

The largest benefits from the Bush tax cuts flowed to high-income taxpayers.

From 2004-2012 (the years for which comparable estimates are available), the top 1 percent of households received average tax cuts of more than $50,000 each year. On average, these households received a total tax cut of over $570,000 over this period.

High-income taxpayers also received the largest tax cuts as a share of their after-tax incomes. The Tax Policy Center estimated that in 2010, the year the tax cuts were fully phased in, they raised the after-tax incomes of the top 1 percent of households by 6.7 percent, while only raising the after-tax incomes of the middle 20 percent of households by 2.8 percent. The bottom 20 percent of households received the smallest tax cuts, with their after-tax incomes increasing by just 1.0 percent due to the tax cuts.

Policymakers enacted the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts with the promise that they would “pay for themselves” by delivering increased economic growth, which would generate higher tax revenues. But even President Bush’s Treasury Department estimated that under the most optimistic scenario, the tax cuts would at best pay for less than 10 percent of their long-term cost with increased growth.

Evidence suggests that the tax cuts — particularly those for high-income households — did not improve economic growth or pay for themselves, but instead ballooned deficits and debt and contributed to a rise in income inequality.

In fact, the economic expansion that lasted from 2001 to 2007 was weaker than average. A review of economic evidence on the tax cuts by Brookings Institution economist William Gale and Dartmouth professor Andrew Samwick, former chief economist on George W. Bush’s Council of Economic Advisers, found that “a cursory look at growth between 2001 and 2007 (before the onset of the Great Recession) suggests that overall growth rate was … mediocre” and that “there is, in short, no first-order evidence in the aggregate data that these tax cuts generated growth.”

In comparison, the economic expansion of the early 1990s — which followed considerable tax increases — produced a much faster rate of job growth and somewhat faster GDP growth than the expansion of the early 2000s. An analysis of business activity between 1996 and 2008 found that even the sharp cut in dividend tax rates in 2003, which proponents claimed would spur immediate business growth, had no significant impact on business investment or employee compensation after 2003.

And, when the tax cuts were scheduled to expire at the end of 2012, extending the high-income tax cuts in particular was projected to have almost no effect on economic growth. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) estimated in 2012 that extending the high-income tax cuts would have boosted GDP by just 0.1 percent in 2013. Indeed, allowing the high-income tax cuts to expire after 2012 does not appear to have had any substantial negative impacts on economic growth, as proponents of the tax cuts had claimed, and the economy has continued to grow steadily since then. This is consistent with the broader empirical literature about taxes on high-income people and economic growth. As one comprehensive review of the empirical literature by three leading tax economists found, “there is no compelling evidence to date of real responses of upper income taxpayers to changes in tax rates.”


Related Solutions

• Describe one situation with real-world examples in which a programmer might want to create a...
• Describe one situation with real-world examples in which a programmer might want to create a loop that tests its condition in the beginning of the loop and one situation in which the condition is tested at the end of the loop. • There are many situations where infinite loops may occur. Discuss those situations and provide best practices for each of the loop types that help avoid writing infinite loops.
Explain why the timing of fiscal policy may be more difficult than the timing of monetary...
Explain why the timing of fiscal policy may be more difficult than the timing of monetary policy.
Consider the effects of the following policy actions. To illustrate their effects identify real world policy...
Consider the effects of the following policy actions. To illustrate their effects identify real world policy situations in which they are used. 1.Setting a maximum quantity produced or employed (available for employment) 2.Setting a minimum price for the product or service
Consider that many politicians are drawn to fiscal policy to grow the economy. Why might this...
Consider that many politicians are drawn to fiscal policy to grow the economy. Why might this be the case? (at least 10 sentences please)
A number of real world complications that make monetary and fiscal policy more challenging than simple...
A number of real world complications that make monetary and fiscal policy more challenging than simple theory would suggest. Given the state of the economy and the causes of that state think back to earlier discussions about the current economy- what should be the appropriate mix of fiscal and monetary policy. Form a Keynesian perspective? From a neoclassical perspective? Which makes the most sense to you? Provide evidence ( include and least one link/citation)to provide support to your conclusion.
Compare and contrast the time lag of fiscal and monetary policies. Alternative perspectives on stabilization policy,...
Compare and contrast the time lag of fiscal and monetary policies. Alternative perspectives on stabilization policy, passive vs active, conservative vs liberal, rule vs discretion. Taylor’s rule on monetary policy, i.e. nominal federal fund rate = inflation rate + 2% + ½ (inflation rate minus 2%) + ½ (GDP gap).
Which of the following time lags creates the biggest problem for fiscal policy? a. impact lag...
Which of the following time lags creates the biggest problem for fiscal policy? a. impact lag b. recognition lag c. data lag d. legislative lag Which of the following time lags creates the biggest problem for monetary policy? a. impact lag b.legislative lag c. recognition lag d. effectiveness lag
please provide one real-life example of fiscal policy is from the fiscal year 2019? write a...
please provide one real-life example of fiscal policy is from the fiscal year 2019? write a paragprah. Thank you
Critics of Keynesian fiscal policy point out that the “lag problem” presents a quite serious     challenge...
Critics of Keynesian fiscal policy point out that the “lag problem” presents a quite serious     challenge to both the theory and the execution of the policy itself. What is this problem, what kinds of lags are there and why is it a weakness?
Describe the differences between fiscal policy and monetary policy. What fiscal and monetary policies might be...
Describe the differences between fiscal policy and monetary policy. What fiscal and monetary policies might be prescribed for an economy in a deep recession? Be sure to distinguish between the monetary and fiscal policy solutions in your answer.
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT