In: Economics
Suppose an increase in air pollution causes capital to wear out more rapidly, doubling the rate of depreciation. How would this affect economic growth?
The three different market impacts
of pollution are: reduced labour productivity; increased health
expenditures; and crop yield losses. They all contribute to a
projection of GDP that's below the projection that excludes the
pollution feedbacks on the economy (Figure 6). At the worldwide
level, the results of labour productivity and health expenditure
impacts still increase significantly relative to GDP. In contrast,
agricultural impacts are relatively stable over time in percentage
of GDP, i.e. in absolute terms these impacts grow more or less at
an equivalent speed as GDP.
The effects of the three different impact categories cannot just be
added up to calculate an overall effect of the market impacts of
pollution on economic process as there are interaction effects that
require to be taken under consideration . In theory, these
interaction effects are often both positive and negative. In the
projection with all impact categories, the general GDP loss is
larger than the sum of the three individual losses. At the
worldwide level this effect is minor (less than 0.1% of GDP in
2060), except for the foremost affected regions, it can increase
GDP losses more significantly.
It is possible to attribute a price to non-market impacts, like the
premature deaths and therefore the costs of pain and affected by
illness, using estimates of willingness-to-pay (WTP) based on
direct valuation studies. The welfare costs of the premature deaths
caused by pollution are calculated using the worth of a statistical
life (VSL). This is a long-established metric, which can be
quantified by aggregating individuals’ WTP to secure a marginal
reduction in the risk of premature death over a given timespan. The
VSL values used are calculated employing a reference OECD value of
2005 USD 3 million then using benefit transfer techniques to
calculate country-specific values following OECD (2012). This is
done on the idea of country-specific income adjustments, with an
income elasticity of 0.8 for high-income countries, 0.9 for
middle-income countries and 1 for low-income countries