In: Economics
Choose any quote on this reading below and explain.
I. Major Themes and Causal Mechanisms "State Power and the Structure of International Trade" operates simul taneously on three levels. Its first sentences announce a program for the revival of the state in studies of international relations: "In recent years, students of international relations have multinationalized, transnation 1 Krasner, "State Power and the Structure of International Trade," World Politics 28 (April 1976). This content downloaded from 146.96.128.36 on Thu, 28 Aug 2014 15:04:13 PM All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 152 WORLD POLITICS alized, bureaucratized and transgovernmentalized the state until it has virtually ceased to exist as an analytic construct_This perspective is at best profoundly misleading" (p. 317). Krasner s rhetoric is dazzling: the core subject matter of political sci ence is threatened and must be recovered. "State Power" sounds the ral lying cry for the defenders of the state. People who look to the state for redress of market unfairness, scholars whose human capital is invested in understanding how states work, and Hobbesian skeptics suspicious of visions of efficiency and harmony can all rally around the statist stan dard. Teaching and writing on this theme in the mid-1970s, after the defeat of the United States in Vietnam, Krasner helped to launch a counterwave of renewed interest in the state against the trends empha sizing economic interdependence, transnational relations, "ungov ernability," and the states alleged economic irrelevance. Leading economists had been more impressed with the advantages of multina tional firms over states. Not long before Krasner wrote, Charles Kindle berger had proclaimed that "the nation-state is just about through as an economic unit."2 Even political scientists sympathetic to the transna tionalist research agenda recoiled from such rhetoric. It was Krasners counterrhetoric that energized a statist reaction?and it mattered little that his article nowhere defines "the state"; contests over definitions also became part of the subsequent scholarly debate. Some of the appeal of "State Power" derives from its clear specifica tion of 2l puzzle. Puzzles are central to social science, and Krasner s puz zle is an important one. Why, he asks, has the world economy vacillated between openness and closure? To clarify this issue, Krasner carefiilly defines the continuum between openness and closure. While acknowl edging the significance of movements of capital, labor, and technology, he focuses on trade. He argues that openness or closure in the structure of international trade can be operationalized by examining tariff levels, trade as a proportion of national product, and the regionalization or globalization of trade. Krasner does not merely present an important puzzle; he provides a way to measure the dependent variable that he has identified. Thus he lays out the basis for a focused research program. "State Power" also advances a strong proposition, as stated above, that hegemonic ascendancy tends to create openness. Indeed, Krasner pro posed a set of explanatory variables?position in the world political economy, defined in terms of size, level of development, and changes in 2 Kindleberger, American Business Abroad: Six Lectures on
"State Power and the Structure of International Trade"
The structure of international trade, identified by the degree of openness for the movement of goods, can best be explained by a state-power theory of international political economy. This theory begins with the assumption that the nature of international economic movements is determined by states acting to maximize national goals. Four goals--aggregate national income, political power, social stability, and economic growth--can be systematically related to the degree of openness in the international trading system for states of different relative sizes and levels of development. This analysis leads to the conclusion that openness is most likely to exist when there is a hegemonic distribution of potential economic power. Time-series data on tariff levels, trade proportions, regional concentration, per capita income, national income, the share of world trade, and share of world investment are then presented. The first three are used to describe the degree of openness in the trading system; the last four, the distribution of state power. The data suggest that the state-power theory should be amended to take into consideration domestic political constraints on state action.
In a Nutshell
Krasner develops a model of receptiveness to open trade based on the interests of states. This contrasts with last week’s readings which focus on societal cleavages that explain the openness to trade liberalization. He sets up this model not to specifically refute other perspectives although presumably, the superiority of his approach is implicit. He does specifically mention wishing to refute the idea that states open a trade policy as the result of international elements beyond the control of any state or system created by states. His specific findings are that trade openness is most likely to increase when there is one dominant and ascending hegemonic power. However, states are not always able to act in their best interest due to past policy choice constraints, therefore often some large-scale exogenous event is needed to act as a catalyst, to sweep away the previous policy environment.
The Model
He calls his model the “state-power” model (SPM). It is trying to explain why we see a policy that is not in line with neo-classical theory. The theory states that open trade maximizes aggregate economic utility and this is what states are seeking to do. Why then do we see protectionism? The answer is that states are pursuing at least four separate goals, and their relative importance and how they interact with freer trade determines policy.
Next, he imagines different international makeups to see which would lead to openness.
Testing the Theory
He looks at tariffs, trade as a proportion of income, and the concentration of trade within specific trading blocs to define periods from 1870-1970 into periods of expanding/contracting free trade. I will not go into all the detail other than to point out the following contradictions highlighted by Krasner:
Amending the Model