Question

In: Economics

Consider a second price auction for a single item with two bidders. Suppose the bidders have...

Consider a second price auction for a single item with two bidders. Suppose the bidders have independent private values, uniformly drawn in the interval [0, 1]. Suppose the seller sets a reserve price p = 0.5; that is, only bids above p = 0.5 can win. If a bidder bids above p and the other bids below p, then the first bidder wins and pays a price p. If both bid above p, then the highest bidder wins and pays the second highest price.

In the Bayesian equilibrium in undominated strategies, what is the probability that the item will not be sold?

Solutions

Expert Solution

In game theory, a Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium (PBE) is an equilibrium concept relevant for dynamic games with incomplete information (sequential Bayesian games). It is a refinement of Bayesian Nash equilibrium (BNE). A PBE has two components - strategies and beliefs:

  • The strategy of a player in given information set determines how this player acts in that information-set. The action may depend on the history. This is similar to a sequential game.
  • The belief of a player in a given information set determines what node in that information-set the player believes that they are playing at. The belief may be a probability distribution over the nodes in the information-set.

In a study, Vickrey (in 1961) showed that when a = 1 the auction has a unique equilibrium in dominant strategies which is symmetric: i puts probability 1 on the bid ti . Again, Milgrom (in 1981) has shown that when a = 0 the auction has a symmetric equilibrium (which is in undominated strategies). In the example here when N = 2, it is a symmetric equilibrium where each bidder bids 0.5 when observing Si = 0, bids 1/2 when observing Si = 1/2 , and bids 1 when observing Si = 1. Thus, for the extremes of a = 0 and a = 1, equilibria exist.

For any N ≥ 2 and any 0.5 > a > 0 there exists m > 0 and ε > 0 such that if m < m and ε < ε, then the second price auction does not have either a symmetric equilibrium or an equilibrium in undominated strategies.

First, note that if bidders use strategies in the closure of the set of undominated strategies, then conditional on any Ti and Si ∈ {0, 1}, a bidder must bid aTi + (1 − a)Si , and conditional on any Ti and Si = 1/2 , a bidder must bid in [aTi , aTi + (1 − a)]. Under a symmetric equilibrium these strategies must also be followed. For example, suppose that instead there was some Ti and Si ∈ {0, 1} such that each i bid above aTi + (1 − a) with positive probability (the argument ruling out bids below is similar). In that case some i would win with positive probability when the price was above aTi + (1 − a) and their value was at most aTi + (1 − a). They could improve their payoff by lowering their bid to aTi + (1 − a). Next, consider the strategy followed by a bidder i conditional on observing Ti = 0, Si = 1/2 . From above, we know that his or her bids are confined to the interval [0, 1 − a]. Let ε < (1−a)/ 2a , so that aε < (1−a)/ 2 . Let us argue that if m is small enough, then neither bidder places positive probability in the range [aε, 1 − a]. Conditional on winning with a bid bi ∈ [aε, 1 − a], if m is small enough, then conditional on the price being below the maximal possible value of 1 − a the overwhelming probability is that the other bidder observed a signal regarding the common component of 0 (all bidders having observed signals of 1 bid at least 1−a). Thus, for small enough m, the overall conditional expected value when winning in this interval is below aε, and so the bidder has a negative expected value conditional on winning in this interval and could improve by instead bidding below aε. So, both bidders conditional on observing Ti = 0, Si = 1/2 , bid in the range [0, aε). A bidder i faces two possibilities in this range. First that the other bidder observed Tj = 0, Sj = 0 and bid 0 in which case the price is 0. This is inconsequential to i’s incentives. Second, the other bidder observed Tj = 0, Sj = 1/2 . In this case, i’s conditional valuation is 1−a 2 > aε and i would strictly prefer to win against the other bidder at any price in [0, aε). This contradicts the fact that both bidders place probability one in this interval. We are left with no possible bids conditional on having observed Ti = 0, Si = 1/2 and so equilibrium does not exist.

The three possible changes to the setting that could potentially restore existence of equilibrium. These are to change the setting so that there are:

(1) finite bidding grids,

(2) type-dependent tie-breaking rules in the auction, or

(3) atomless type and information distributions.


Related Solutions

Consider a second price auction with 2 bidders, 1 and 2, who have values for the...
Consider a second price auction with 2 bidders, 1 and 2, who have values for the good of 20 and 80, respectively. Each knows what the other bidder’s valuation is so there is no uncertainty. (a) Show that choosing a bid equal to one’s valuation is a weakly dominant strategy for bidder 1. (b) Show that if each bidder plays a weakly dominant strategy, the bidder with the highest value always wins the good (c) Is it a Nash equilibrium...
Consider a private value auction with 2 bidders. The auction is carried out as a second...
Consider a private value auction with 2 bidders. The auction is carried out as a second price sealed bid auction where in case of a tie between the bidders, the winner is selected by a coin toss. The seller has valuation of the good of zero and will accept any bid at or greater than zero. Each bidder knows his/her own valuation, v, and does not know the valuation of the other bidder. It is common knowledge that the bidder...
Consider a second-price sealed-bid auction. Suppose bidders' valuations are v1=10 and v2=10. Select all that apply....
Consider a second-price sealed-bid auction. Suppose bidders' valuations are v1=10 and v2=10. Select all that apply. (PLEASE EXPLAIN CHOICES COMPLETEY) a. One bidder submitting a bid equal to 10 and the other submitting a bid equal to 0 is a Nash equilibrium. b. Bidding a value b1 equal to her own valuation v1 is a weakly dominated strategy for bidder 1. c. Both bidders submitting bids equal to 0 is a Nash equilibrium. d. Both bidders submitting bids equal to...
Game theory: Analyze the second price" auction. There are two bidders and one object being sold...
Game theory: Analyze the second price" auction. There are two bidders and one object being sold by auction. Each bidder knows what the object is worth to him, but not what it is worth to the other bidder. In other words, the object is worth v1 to bidder 1 and v2 to bidder 2. Bidder 1 knows v1 but not v2, while bidder 2 knows v2 but not v1. In the sealed bid second price auction, each bidder privately submits...
Question 6. There are two bidders in a sealed-bid, second-price auction. The object for sale has...
Question 6. There are two bidders in a sealed-bid, second-price auction. The object for sale has a common value. Each bidder, i = 1,2, receives a signal i that is independently and uniformly distributed on the interval [0, 1]. The true value of the object, v, is the average of the two signals, v = (σ1 + σ2) / 2 (a) If bidder 1 gets the signal σ = 0.7, how much does he think the object is worth? (b)...
Consider 45 risk-neutral bidders who are participating in a second-price, sealed-bid auction. It is commonly known...
Consider 45 risk-neutral bidders who are participating in a second-price, sealed-bid auction. It is commonly known that bidders have independent private values. Based on this information, we know the optimal bidding strategy for each bidder is to: A. bid their own valuation of the item. B. shade their bid to just below their own valuation. C. bid according to the following bid function: b = v − (v − L)/n. D. bid one penny above their own valuation to ensure...
Auction Auction Price Age of Item Number Bidders 1 $946 113 9 2 $1,336 126 10...
Auction Auction Price Age of Item Number Bidders 1 $946 113 9 2 $1,336 126 10 3 $744 115 7 4 $1,979 182 11 5 $1,522 150 9 6 $1,235 127 13 7 $1,483 159 9 8 $1,152 117 13 9 $1,545 175 8 10 $1,262 168 7 11 $845 127 7 12 $1,055 108 14 13 $1,253 132 10 14 $1,297 137 9 15 $1,147 137 8 16 $1,080 115 12 17 $1,550 182 8 18 $1,047 156 6...
We consider a GSP auction with four bidders, A, B, C and D. Since there are...
We consider a GSP auction with four bidders, A, B, C and D. Since there are four bidders only the three highest bidders will be displayed). The click frequency of the first, second and third positions are 100 clicks/hour, 75 clicks/hour and 35 clicks/hour, respectively. Bidders’valuation per click are vA = 10, vB = 6, vC = 4, vD = 3. Bidder B, C and D bid 5, 3 and 1, respectively. What is the optimal bid for A?
Second price auction is quite similar to a first price auction(each player bids secrectly choosing a...
Second price auction is quite similar to a first price auction(each player bids secrectly choosing a nonnegative real number) and each player i value the object viwhere v1 > v2 > ....>vn > 0, except that the winner pays the amount of the second highest bid. Prove that for player i, bidding vi is a weakly dominant strategy. That is, prove that regardless of the actions of the other players, player i payoff when bidding vi is at least as...
1. Queen Elizabeth has decided to auction off the crown jewels. There are two bidders: the...
1. Queen Elizabeth has decided to auction off the crown jewels. There are two bidders: the Sultan and the Sheikh. Each will simultaneously submit a bid in a sealed envelope; the highest bidder will win, and pay what he bid. (This is a “First Price Auction”.) The Sultan is only allowed to bid an odd number: 1, 3, 5, 7, or 9. The Sheikh is only allowed to bid an even number: 2, 4, 6, 8, or 10. The Sultan...
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT