In: Economics
please explain the Stolper-Samuelson Theorem. How is this theorem different fromHeckscher–Ohlin (H–O) theory and Comparative advantage theory?
The Stolper–Samuelson theorem is a basic theorem in
Heckscher–Ohlin trade theory. It describes the relationship between
relative prices of output and relative factor rewards—specifically,
real wages and real returns to capital.The theorem states
that—under specific economic assumptions (constant returns to
scale, perfect competition, equality of the number of factors to
the number of products)—a rise in the relative price of a good will
lead to a rise in the real return to that factor which is used most
intensively in the production of the good, and conversely, to a
fall in the real return to the other factor. The Stolper-Samuelson
theorem demonstrates how changes in output prices affect the prices
of the factors when positive production and zero economic profit
are maintained in each industry . The Stolper-Samuelson theorem
(SST) simply suggests that, in any particular country, a rise in
the relative (producer) prices of the labour intensive good will
make labour better off and capital worse-off, and vice-versa,
provided that some amount of each good is being produced.The
Stolper-Samuelson theorem is one of the central results of
Heckscher-Ohlin theory, itself one of the principal theories of
international trade. It provides a definite answer to a central
question in applied economics: What is the effect of changes in the
prices of goods, caused for example by changes in tariffs, on the
prices of factors of production. As first presented by Wolfgang
Stolper and Paul A. Samuelson (1941), it dealt with a very special
framework with many restrictive assumptions, most notably that the
economy consists of only two broad sectors, and that production
uses only two factors (often labeled capital and labor). However,
subsequent theoretical work has shown that essential features of
the theorem hold much more generally. It has also been applied to a
range of empirical issues, including the effects of increased
globalization on income distribution in developed countries, and
the long-run political allegiances of classes and interest groups.
The Stolper-Samuelson theorem in its original setting can be
explained intuitively as follows. Suppose that one sector produces
exports and the other produces goods which compete directly with
imports. Suppose in addition that the import-competing sector is
relatively "labor-intensive," meaning that it uses a higher ratio
of labor to capital than the export sector. Now ask what will be
the effect of a tariff or some other change, which raises the
relative price of the import-competing sector's output. Clearly
this will encourage that sector to expand. Provided that the
economy is at or close to full employment of both factors, this
expansion must come at the expense of the export sector. The
combined expansion of the relatively labor-intensive sector and
contraction of the relatively capital-intensive sector raises the
aggregate demand for labor relative to capital, and so puts upward
pressure on the wage. Because the price of exports has not changed,
a higher wage must imply an absolute fall in the return to capital.
This in turn implies that the wage must rise by even more than the
price of imports. Thus, when import-competing goods are relatively
labor-intensive, wage earners gain and capital owners lose,
irrespective of which bundle of goods they consume. Put simply, in
this case, protection unambiguously raises real wages.Another key
assumption is that all factors are fully mobile between sectors.
Relaxing this for one of the two factors in the simplest case
yields the specific-factors model, which provides an illuminating
contrast with the Heckscher-Ohlin model. In line with the general
results of the last paragraph, protection continues to raise the
real return of one factor, the one specific to the import-competing
sector, and to lower the real return of another factor, that
specific to the export sector. However, its effect on the real
return of the mobile factor is now ambiguous. The specific-factors
model can also be viewed as depicting a short-run equilibrium. Over
time, the specific factors lose their distinctiveness and become
intersector-ally mobile, so the Stolper-Samuelson predictions are
restored.
The Heckscher-Ohlin model is an economic
theory that proposes that countries export what they can most
efficiently and plentifully produce. Also referred to as the H-O
model or 2x2x2 model, it's used to evaluate trade and, more
specifically, the equilibrium of trade between two countries that
have varying specialties and natural resources.The model emphasizes
the export of goods requiring factors of production that a country
has in abundance. It also emphasizes the import of goods that a
nation cannot produce as efficiently. It takes the position that
countries should ideally export materials and resources of which
they have an excess, while proportionately importing those
resources they need.The Heckscher-Ohlin model explains
mathematically how a country should operate and trade when
resources are imbalanced throughout the world. It pinpoints a
preferred balance between two countries, each with its
resources.
The model isn't limited to tradable commodities. It also
incorporates other production factors such as labor. The costs of
labor vary from one nation to another, so countries with cheap
labor forces should focus primarily on producing labor-intensive
goods, according to the model. Although the Heckscher-Ohlin model
appears reasonable, most economists have had difficulty finding
evidence to support it. A variety of other models have been used to
explain why industrialized and developed countries traditionally
lean toward trading with one another and rely less heavily on trade
with developing markets.
Heckscher-Ohlin theory, in economics, a theory of comparative
advantage in international trade according to which countries in
which capital is relatively plentiful and labour relatively scarce
will tend to export capital-intensive products and import
labour-intensive products, while countries in which labour is
relatively plentiful and capital relatively scarce will tend to
export labour-intensive products and import capital-intensive
products. The theory was developed by the Swedish economist Bertil
Ohlin (1899–1979) on the basis of work by his teacher the Swedish
economist Eli Filip Heckscher (1879–1952). Some countries are
relatively well-endowed with capital: the typical worker has plenty
of machinery and equipment to assist with the work. In such
countries, wage rates generally are high; as a result, the costs of
producing labour-intensive goods—such as textiles, sporting goods,
and simple consumer electronics—tend to be more expensive than in
countries with plentiful labour and low wage rates. On the other
hand, goods requiring much capital and only a little labour
(automobiles and chemicals, for example) tend to be relatively
inexpensive in countries with plentiful and cheap capital. Thus,
countries with abundant capital should generally be able to produce
capital-intensive goods relatively inexpensively, exporting them in
order to pay for imports of labour-intensive goods.