Question

In: Economics

4. Members of a fishing village in New England have open access to a fishery (no...

4. Members of a fishing village in New England have open access to a fishery (no one in the village explicitly owns the fishery). As long as an individual is a resident of the village, the individual can harvest as much fish as he wants from the fishery. All non‐residents are not allowed to fish.  Given this scenario, is the equilibrium level of fishery harvest “too much” or “too little” or equal to the social optimum? Explain why this occurs.  Support your answer by drawing the private and social, marginal cost and marginal benefit curves for fish. Identify the deadweight loss area if any exists.

Solutions

Expert Solution

On 19 July 2010, President Obama signed a National Ocean Policy executive order endorsing findings of the Administration’s Interagency Ocean Policy Task Force, including “ecosystem-based” and “adaptive” marine resource management (Interagency Ocean Policy Task Force 2009). Meanwhile, the National Marine Fisheries Service of the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) was finalizing a national policy encouraging the use of fishery catch shares. Catch shares include limited access privileges, individual fishing quotas (ITQs), and quotas held by groups such as harvest cooperatives or fleet sectors (NOAA 2009). Both policies were informed by years of environmental non-governmental organizations (ENGOs) lobbying of NOAA and the White House Council on Environmental Quality, by Congressional mandates embedded in the Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act (FCMA)—particularly its amendments in 1996 and 2006—and by reports from bodies such as the National Academy of Sciences, U.S. Oceans Commission, and Pew Oceans Commission (National Research Council 1999, 2006, Pew Oceans Commission 2003, U.S. Commission on Ocean Policy 2004, Joint Oceans Commission Initiative 2009). Despite this breadth of input, public discussion appears not to consider the possibility that ecosystem-based management and catch shares are at odds: historically intertwined, but conceptually divergent.

Although policy conflict is nothing new, this particular divergence provides entrée to more empirically robust conversations about the future of marine resource management. Evidence from the nation’s oldest commercial fishery, the New England groundfishery (which includes bottom-dwelling species, such as cod (Gadus morhua), haddock (Melanogrammus aeglefinus), winter flounder (Pleuronectes americanus), dabs (Hippoglossoides platessoides), grey sole (Glyptocephalus cynoglossus), pollock (Pollachius virens), whiting (Merluccius bilinearis), red hake (Urophycis chuss), and redfish (Sebastes fasciatus)) and, especially, case material from the state of Maine suggest that catch shares may deter the development of ecosystem-based management. Catch shares shift the attention of managers, fishermen, and the public away from integrated understandings of fished ecosystems and fishing practices, and toward paper fish. The term “paper fish” was coined by fishermen to refer to federal permits allowing fishing activities based on single-species stock assessments, implying that the assessments are detached from the complexities of real-world fishing practice and fished ecosystems. (The few fisherwomen in New England self-identify as “fishermen,” so that term is used here.)

The National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration now boasts 14 catch share programs in the United States. Although some fishermen have implemented catch shares with relative enthusiasm, others are deeply concerned about long-term social–ecological damage. Public comments collected by NOAA in 2010 and summarized in Appendix 1 revealed a strong opposition to catch shares among both commercial and recreational fishermen, reaching 83% and 90% respectively. Maine’s fishing communities have long been among the most resistant to catch shares. Opposition grows principally from socioeconomic considerations, specifically the concern that catch shares consolidate fishery access and decision making in the hands of fewer, larger, and less locally committed firms, but it also reflects concerns about ecosystem impacts. Similar objections are raised by fishermen in other locales, but often with less unanimity.

Pursuant to this argument, this paper briefly summarizes scholarship on ecosystem- and catch share-based fisheries policy in the U.S. context, presents the groundfish case study and discusses its implications, and concludes with a glance toward possible futures.

Despite the legal requirement that managers examine and mitigate potential effects of policies on fishing communities (Magnuson-Stevens Fishery Conservation and Management Act of 2006), these types of data are conspicuously absent from most management discussions. While some social scientists in fisheries management acknowledge and lament these shortcomings (e.g., Sepez et al. 2006), little headway has been made toward including detailed, site-specific, socio-cultural data on fishing communities in the decision-making process. On the rare occasions when managers do include non-economic social data in assessments, these data tend to come from broad, large-scale datasets (e.g., US Census), garnered from available online sources, or based on surveys or interviews administered during brief visits to fishing communities. The data collected are often limited and typically focus directly on involvement in fisheries (e.g., Himes-Cornell et al. 2013). The complex relationships between fishing peoples and their resource bases, however, are difficult to capture in such broad scale data or numerical summaries (Sepez et al. 2006).

When managers exclude socio-cultural data the ramifications can be serious. Exclusion of these data can paint simplified pictures of communities, with unintended consequences, such as perpetuating inequality, reducing resilience, and disturbing networks of informal institutions important for resource sustainability (Poe et al. 2014). This is especially true for indigenous communities, for whom historical conditions are particularly important to understand or meaningfully assess contemporary conditions. Thus, we posit that relational place-making can provide a useful lens through which to understand the social and cultural dimensions of fisheries dependent communities for inclusion in management decision-making. Such a framework allows for integration and comparison of socio-cultural values with the economic indicators and programs currently used in management, providing a useful point of entry into management discussions. Below, we provide an example of the framework’s utility, examining the successes and failures of a particular policy, the community development quota (CDQ) program, in the Pribilof Island communities of St. George and St. Paul, Alaska.

Many fishing communities are struggling today. Through policies of access privatization and declines in resources, residents are losing access to their resource bases. Despite this, and in the face of economic collapse, people are choosing to stay in these communities. These socially created places are therefore important. They represent shared history, a sense of community and family, as well as a way-of-life quite different than those found in urban spaces. In indigenous communities, place furthermore represents a connection to sovereignty, cultural heritage, and sense of stewardship toward land and resources. Only by understanding all these factors, and the importance with which residents view them, can policy-makers fulfill their obligations to achieve community sustainability and minimize adverse impacts on communities (e.g., Gehan and Hallowell 2012; Executive Order 12898 of February 11 1994).

Fishery policies for indigenous and rural fishing communities cannot, therefore, be successful if the authors of these plans do not understand local goals and needs. While gaining this understanding is a difficult task, it is a worthwhile one. As Campbell and Hunt (2012) explain, conflicts between indigenous and government goals do not reflect different priorities—both groups desire to see increased income and opportunities for struggling communities; rather the disagreement centers around who sets the development agenda and how success is defined. Thus policy makers should be clear in stating goals and how these goals articulate with local understandings and desires.

As a tool to aid in this endeavor, we propose the use of relational place-making as an analytical framework to provide complex social science data to inform and help structure discussions around community-based fisheries policy. While economic markers are commonly used as indicators for measuring the success of policies, and development programs in particular, they have many limitations. Economic markers cannot predict, describe, or explain conflicts between insider and outsider ideas about development and goals for the future. They cannot adequately demonstrate whether local well-being has actually increased or decreased as the result of an intervention. And, finally, they cannot capture the loss of non-market, locally valued, place characteristics. Relational place-making, in contrast, can do all of these things.


Related Solutions

4. Members of a fishing village in New England have open access to a fishery (no...
4. Members of a fishing village in New England have open access to a fishery (no one in the village explicitly owns the fishery). As long as an individual is a resident of the village, the individual can harvest as much fish as he wants from the fishery. All non‐residents are not allowed to fish.  Given this scenario, is the equilibrium level of fishery harvest “too much” or “too little” or equal to the social optimum? Explain why this occurs.  Support your...
Members of a fishing village in New England have open access to a fishery (no one...
Members of a fishing village in New England have open access to a fishery (no one in the village explicitly owns the fishery). As long as an individual is a resident of the village, the individual can harvest as much fish as he wants from the fishery. All non‐residents are not allowed to fish. Given this scenario, is the equilibrium level of fishery harvest “too much” or “too little” or equal to the social optimum? Explain why this occurs. Support...
1. Download the EXCEL file: Access Exercise Tables 2. Open a new blank database in ACCESS...
1. Download the EXCEL file: Access Exercise Tables 2. Open a new blank database in ACCESS and name it “Exercise-Your Name” where you replace Your Name with your name. 3. Import each worksheet in the EXCEL file into ACCESS as a separate table as follows: a. External Data Tab -> Import Excel icon b. In the dialog box browse for the destination of the excel file you saved in step 1, it should default to “import the source data in...
4. A study in New England Journal of Medicine wanted to estimate the proportion of all...
4. A study in New England Journal of Medicine wanted to estimate the proportion of all needle injection-drug users, who test HIV-positive in New Haven, Connecticut by selecting a sample. How large should the sample size be so that the confidence interval for proportion has a margin of error within ±5% of the population proportion with 99% confidence level if a preliminary sample found that 67.5% of needles used by injection-drug users are HIV-positive?
4-5. In the summer of 2003, The New England Journal of Medicine published results of some...
4-5. In the summer of 2003, The New England Journal of Medicine published results of some Scandinavian research. Men diagnosed with prostate cancer were randomly assigned to either undergo surgery or not. Among the 347 men who had surgery (group 1), 9 eventually died of prostate cancer compared with 31 of the 348 men (group 2) who did not have surgery. The researchers want to determine if surgery increases the chance of survival. Let p1: proportion of men that survived...
The United Nation SDGs four (4) on education wants everyone to have access to inclusive, equitable...
The United Nation SDGs four (4) on education wants everyone to have access to inclusive, equitable quality education. The government of Ghana upon this realization has as a matter of urgency rolled out important policy on education to build enough capacity for the country through its flagship programme of free SHS. a. From the perspective of normative economics, at what point would the labor market in Ghana be judged to be at a point of optimality? b. What imperfections might...
open a new small business like frozen pizza, describe 4 types of plans and develop each...
open a new small business like frozen pizza, describe 4 types of plans and develop each one for your products
Imagine yourself preparing to open a new restaurant. While you have never owned a restaurant yourself,...
Imagine yourself preparing to open a new restaurant. While you have never owned a restaurant yourself, you have over twenty years of experience in the industry, starting as a host(ess) and working up to a manager. You have approached many banks for loans, and have been turned down by all, since the restaurant business is very risky. What avenues might you pursue to gain the financing you need? For example, think outside of the box when it comes to considering...
When Taco Bell wanted to open many new locations, the company’s leaders knew they would have...
When Taco Bell wanted to open many new locations, the company’s leaders knew they would have trouble hiring enough managers. The solution was to train employees to work as , working together to hire their own colleagues, manage inventory, and do financial reporting.
4. A new machine will cost $17,000 and will have a resale value of $14,000 after...
4. A new machine will cost $17,000 and will have a resale value of $14,000 after five years. Special tooling will cost $5,000. The tooling will have a resale value of $2,500 after five years. Maintenance will be $2,000 per year. The effect annual interest rate is 6%. The average annual cost of ownership during the next five years will be most nearly. (A) $2,000 (B) $2,300 (C) $4,300 (D) $5,500 5. An old covered wooden bridge can be strengthened...
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT