In: Economics
This paper provides the first real-world evidence of Giffen
behavior, i.e., upward sloping demand. Subsidizing the prices of
dietary staples for extremely poor households in two provinces of
China, we find strong evidence of Giffen behavior for rice in
Hunan, and weaker evidence for wheat in Gansu. The data provide new
insight into the consumption behavior of the poor, who act as
though maximizing utility subject to subsistence concerns. We find
that their elasticity of demand depends significantly, and
nonlinearly, on the severity of their poverty. The “Law of Demand,”
which holds that as the price of a good increases, consumers’
demand for that good should decrease, is one of the bedrock
principles of microeconomics. Economists have long recognized,
however, that the axioms of consumer theory do not guarantee that
demand curves must slope downward, and that the Law of Demand,
while descriptively valid in many situations, may not apply to very
poor consumers facing subsistence concerns. Alfred Marshall first
publicized this idea in the 1895 edition of his Principles of
Economics:
Mr. Giffen has pointed out, a rise in the price of bread makes so
large a drain on the resources of the poorer labouring families and
raises so much the marginal utility of money to them, that they are
forced to curtail their consumption of meat and the more expensive
farinaceous foods: and, bread being still the cheapest food which
they can get and will take,they consume more, and not less of it.
Giffen behavior has long played an important, though controversial,
role in economic pedagogy, as well as in the history of economic
thought.Finding convincing evidence of such behavior is important,
however, for economic theory more broadly. The fact that there has,
to date, been no convincing evidence of Giffen behavior stands as a
minor embarrassment to economists (John H. Nachbar 1998), one that
is reflected in the discussion of the Giffen phenomenon often being
presented as a paradox of economic
theory rather than as a real (or even possible) mode of behavior
(e.g., Stigler 1947). This lack of evidence has prompted a range of
reactions among economists. Some have interpreted it as support for
the descriptive validity of the Law of Demand: Perhaps as
persuasive a proof [of the “Law of Demand”] as is readily
summarized is this: if an economist were to demonstrate its failure
in a particular market at a particular time, he would be assured of
immortality, professionally speaking, and rapid promotion while
still alive. Since most economists would not dislike either reward,
we may assume that the total absence of exceptions is not from lack
of trying to find them. The conditions under which we would expect
Giffen behavior can be demonstrated by elaborating Marshall’s
statement.
Imagine an impoverished consumer near a subsistence level of
nutrition, whose diet consists of only two foods, a “basic” or
staple good (in Marshall’s case, bread) and a “fancy” good (meat).
The basic good offers a high level of calories at low cost, while
the fancy good is preferred because of its taste but provides few
calories per unit currency. A poor consumer will therefore eat a
lot of bread in order to get enough calories to meet his basic
needs and use whatever money he has left over to purchase meat.
Now, if the price of
bread increases, he can no longer afford the original bundle of
foods. And if he increases his consumption of meat, he will fall
below his required caloric intake. So, he must instead increase his
consumption of bread (which is still the cheapest source of
calories) and cut back on meat. The Giffen phenomenon illustrates
the potential significance of the wealth effects of price changes
for extremely poor households. Although the price increase makes
the staple less attractive in relative terms, the fact that it
makes the consumer so much poorer (in real terms) forces him to
consume more bread. Translating this to the language of consumer
theory, the conditions under which Giffen behavior is likely to be
observed, therefore, include that the good in question be strongly
inferior and that expenditure on that good comprise a large portion
of the consumer’s budget. In light of these observations, we can
state a set of conditions under which Giffen behavior is most
likely to be observed:
C1: Households are poor enough that they face subsistence nutrition
concerns.
C2: Households consume a very simple diet, including a basic
(staple) and a fancy good.
C3: The basic good is the cheapest source of calories available,
comprises a large part of the diet/budget, and has no ready
substitute.