In: Economics
Indira Gandhi, the late Indian prime minister once said: 'The idea of a better world is one in which medical discoveries will be free of patents and there will be no profiteering from life and death.'. Patents are property rights over intellectual discoveries. What do you think of Gandhi’s statement above? in 600 words
Public health laws, national drug policy and the patent system are intensely inter-related. This was explained by Prime Minister Indira Gandhi while speaking at the World Health Assembly in Geneva on May 6, 1981. In her words:
"Affluent societies are spending vast sums of money understandably on the search for new products and processes to alleviate suffering and to prolong life. In the process, the drug manufacture has become a powerful industry."
She added, on the patent system: "My idea of a better ordered world is one in which medical discoveries would be free of patents and there would be no profiteering from life or death."
In this historic session, the participating countries unanimously adopted a resolution for "Global Strategy on Health for All". Since then there have been laudable contributions by science and technology to tackle successfully many health problem areas. While there is a substantial unfinished agenda on the health front, new and formidable challenges have been thrown up by an unequal treaty on all-pervasive economic and social aspects by the Final Act embodying the results of the Uruguay Round negotiations. In particular, the TRIPS agreement is the most contentious part of the Final Act. The aim of this agreement is to enforce globally tough standards in respect of several forms of intellectual property, which include patents, trademarks, protection of undisclosed information, and so on, forgetting the goals expressed by Indira Gandhi in regard to freeing of medical discoveries from the patent system.
A patent is a monopoly right granted by a state to a person to exploit and benefit from the invention patented by him for a particular period. Thereafter, it passes into the public domain. The theory upon which the patent system is based is that the opportunity of acquiring exclusive rights in an invention stimulates technical progress in four ways: first, that it encourages research and invention; second, that it induces an inventor to disclose his discoveries instead of keeping them as a trade secret; third, that it offers a reward for the expenses of developing inventions to the stage at which they are commercially practicable; and fourth, that it provides an inducement to invest capital in new lines of production which might not appear profitable if many competing producers embarked on them simultaneously. Manufacturers would not be prepared to develop and produce important machinery if others could get the results of their work with impunity
Now that India has signed the treaty, though most unwillingly, it is committed to introducing pharmaceutical product patents 2004, a value analysis i.e. cost-benefit analysis of this move is essential for India. First some history.
The Indian Patents Act 1970
This legislation implemented in 1972 made pharmaceutical product
innovations, as well as those for food and agrochemicals,
unpatentable in India thus greatly weakening IPR protection. It
allowed innovations patented elsewhere to befreely copied and
marketed in India. Therefore foreign firms did not find patenting
in India worthwhile. This act further restricted import of finished
formulations, imposed high tariff rates and introduced strict price
control regulation with the 1970 Drugs Price Control Order. This
gave a boost to the Indian pharmaceutical industry.
India beyond 2004
In granting patents, there is a trade-off between the costs
incurred by the country granting the patent due to monopoly pricing
and the gains accruing to it due to encouragement to innovative
efforts.
Costs
With the introduction of patents, the inventor will try to maximise
his profits and therefore price his drug higher than if there were
no patents. Correspondingly the consumption of the drug will be
lower. This represents an indirect welfare loss to Indian consumers
because of higher prices associated with introducing product
patents. In addition to this are the direct costs of administering
the patent system and enforcing patentee rights through the courts
in case there are infringement disputes.
Benefits
The inventor is able to earn higher profits and therefore would
likely invest more in R&D and drug discovery and testing, in
turn increasing consumer welfare. Also, patent laws require
specifications to be disclosed to all and therefore information
about new technologies becomes more quickly available to others as
an input into their own R&D. Moreover the innovating firm is
able to reveal its innovation without losing control and hence can
sub-contract parts of the development work at lower cost to
countries like India.
The blurring line between costs and benefits
The benefit in the form of increased consumer welfare from
patent rights in India might turn out to be a cost if all profits
accrue to foreigners and funds are transferred out of India.
Foreign patentees earn income from patents in two ways:
1. In the form of royalties if production remains under license in
India
2. In the form of export profits if the drugs are imported.
In the case of imports India faces further costs in terms loss of
employment, forex outflow and loss of self-sufficiency i.e. if
strategies shift from imitative R&D to directly purchasing
technology. On the other hand, if these two strategies are not
substitutes to each other, this could turn out to be beneficial for
India if such technology purchase spurs domestic research efforts.
These concerns, however, do not arise in the case of patents
granted to Indians.
The patentee receives profits on his innovation until the patent
expires, after which there will be a generic entry which will bid
down the prices. In India, lack of protection for pharmaceutical
products means that Indians can manufacture and sell on-patent
drugs in India and then access the world markets faster than
foreign firms when the patent expires. Thus, patent protection in
India will confer on the patentee an additional benefit (over and
above profits from sales in India), that is, a decrease in the rate
of erosion of his profits from sales in the world markets after
patent expiry. The cost to India would be to those Indian firms who
hitherto enjoyed the first mover advantage in accessing the world
markets. All this depends on how India is viewed as a destination
for R&D investment. If profits from such newly created markets
are viewed to be only marginally incremental, then India might face
higher consumer drug prices and a loss of industry profit and
employment, for little gain in new pharmaceuticals.
Estimating the magnitudes
The magnitude of costs due to introduction of patents will depend
on how much more can the patentee charge for his patented drug and
how much is the loss in consumer welfare. In India, general income
levels are low and consumers directly pay for the drugs (due to
lack of penetration of medical insurance). Therefore consumers will
be sensitive to prices. Also, there are less effective but cheaper
substitutes available in almost all the cases. This limits the
extent to which higher prices can be charged and acts as a downward
pressure on prices. One consideration that would push the price
upwards is the fact that global reference pricing is very common in
developing markets, that is, price for newly introduced drugs is
usually linked to its price elsewhere, either explicitly or through
regulations. Patentees seek to maximize global profits and
therefore if prices are increased in developed countries, it will
have a direct fallout on prices in developing countries. But the
price control regime in India would play a very significant role in
limiting prices, more so because there is nothing in the GATT
treaty which prevents such price regulating actions. Some drugs
might be entirely exempt from the price control allowing the
patentee to charge his own prices. But keeping in view the price
elasticity of demand, especially in countries like India, this will
not be of much significance in terms of loss in consumer
welfare.
Generics the other profit rectangle.
Once the patent on a drug expires, it is termed a "generic". Till
now Indian firms enjoyed tremendous advantage in the generics
market, which might be somewhat eroded post- 2004. However India
enjoys the advantage of lower manufacturing costs and capital
costs. Moreover it is a significant player in the bulk drugs
business and Indian firms are leveraging this fact to become
important players in the formulations market, regardless of whether
they will continue to enjoy the first mover advantage.
Effect on pharmaceutical production in India
Once patent protection is available, patent-owning firms may
choose either to export their patented drugs to India, thereby
replacing domestic production, or they may chose to produce in
India through a subsidiary or under license to Indian firms.
Concerns about global price differentials makes local, low cost,
production attractive as a way to justify Indian prices which are
lower than those charged in developed country markets. Even the
Drug Price Control Order may not act as a hindrance. Ceiling prices
are determined as a mark-up on input costs.
This means that there is a 'transfer-price loophole'. An MNC may
export the patented active ingredient to its Indian subsidiary at
an artificially high transfer price and thereby attain a higher
controlled price for its formulations. This would give
patent-owning MNCs an incentive to produce bulk drug inputs
elsewhere and then import them into India. While the availability
of strong intellectual property protection is necessary, other
considerations, like tax advantages, are also important in choosing
a manufacturing location for on-patent drugs. Further, unlike
generic drugs, manufacturing costs are a small component of the
price of patented drugs and therefore India's advantages as a
low-cost manufacturer would not be particularly useful in
attracting investment in local production facilities. So, while the
largest part of pharmaceutical production should be unaffected,
only some part of the local production of on-patent drugs will be
replaced by imports.
The following facts are noteworthy to gauge the impact of the
introduction of pharmaceutical patents in India:
1. Consistent growth rate of the Indian economy
2. Rising income levels
3. Increasing penetration of insurance on all fronts, especially
after allowing entry of private players.
4. For the 60% of the "poor" in India, who currently do not have
access to pharmaceuticals, price rise and demand sensitivity due to
patent introduction is irrelevant. Thus only a small part of the
market will be affected by the new regime.
5. India is governed by a government which relies more on populist
politics for survival and this would ensure that the best interests
of the population is kept in mind without buckling too much under
international pressures. All in all, India stands to gain more in
the new patent regime with the inherent costs being marginalized by
several factors.