In: Accounting
Please prove American inequality boundary in the options market.
All of the options that we have considered thus far have been of
the European variety: exercise is permitted only at the termination
of the contract. These are, by and large, relatively simple to
price and hedge, at least under the hypotheses of the Black-Sholes
model, as pricing entails only the evaluation of a single
expectation. American options, which may be exercised at any time
up to expiration, are considerably more complicated, because to
price or hedge these options one must account for many (infinitely
many!) different possible exercise policies. For certain options
with convex payoff functions, such as call options on stocks that
pay no dividends, the optimal policy is to exercise only at
expiration. In most other cases, including put options, there is
also an optimal exercise policy; however, this optimal policy is
rarely simple or easily computable. We shall consider the pricing
and optimal exercise of American options in the simplest nontrivial
setting, the Black-Sholes model, where the underlying asset Stock
pays no dividends and has a price process St that behaves, under
the risk-neutral measure Q, as a simple geometric
Brownian motion: (1) St = S0 exp σWt + (r − σ 2 /2)t
Here r ≥ 0, the riskless rate of return, is constant, and
Wt is a standard Wiener process under Q.
For any American option on the underlying asset Stock, the
admissible exercise policies must be stopping times with respect to
the natural filtration (Ft)0≤t≤T of the Wiener process Wt .
If F(s) is the payoff of an American option exercised when the
stock price is s, and if T is the expiration date of the option,
then its value Vt at time t ≤ T is (2) Vt = sup τ :t≤τ≤T E(F(Sτ )e
−r(τ−t) | Ft).
2. Call Options Recall that a call option has payoff (s − K)+ if
exercised when the stock price is s.
Here, as always, K is the strike price of the option. Note that,
for each fixed K, the payoff function (s−K)+ is convex in the
argument.
1. The optimal exercise policy for the owner of an American call
option is to hold the option until expiration, that is, τ = T.
Proof. Let τ ≤ T be any stopping time. If the American option were
exercised at time τ , the payoff would be (Sτ − K)+, and so the
value at time zero to a holder of the option planning to exercise
at the stopping time τ would be E(Sτ − K)+e −rτ ≤ E(Sτ e −rτ − Ke
−rT )+, using the fact that τ ≤ T.
Now recall that the discounted price process :
Ste −rt t≥0 is a martingale. Since the function x 7→ (x − C)+ is
convex, the following lemma implies that E(Sτ e −rτ − Ke −rT )+ ≤
E(ST e −rT − Ke −rT )+.