In: Economics
I like to ask this question each year. To provide you with some color, consider in answering that right now the federal government purchases one in every five gallons of milk sold in the U.S. and that it is illegal for sellers to sell milk to me and you below a mandated minimum price (note that some other industries have wholesalers and retailers execute these arrangements voluntarily – it happened to us when we were selling Titleist Pro-V1 golf balls when they first hit the market over a decade ago). Furthermore, as if the milk market isn’t curdled enough, we restrict how much foreign dairy comes into the US and we then place tariffs on the stuff that does come in.
The following question has several subsections:
Answer (a): In a free market economy, the buyers and sellers are usually under no restriction and the price in the market is determined by the demand and supply functions. There is no external pressure of taxation or any restraint on the seller or on the buyer. IN a free market economy, both the buyer and the seller set up their optimal price and optimal demand respectively. Since the market clearing price or other words, the equilibrium price is $2, it means that at $2 , the producers surplus is optima, and so is the consumers surplus. The total welfare is also maximum at this price. At anything lesser or more than $2, the total welfare will decline as the welfare of either of the producers or the consumers will fall with the other party’s welfare rising.
Answer (b): With the imposition of the minimum milk price rule to $3 per gallon, the producer surplus will increase, as there is a 50% rise in the revenue that they would now be earning. Their surplus will be extra normal. Whereas, the consumers surplus will decline, as the consumer is now having to pay 50% more than what he needed to pay earlier. This will reduce the total surplus or welfare in the economy. Such an idea is good from the economic standpoint, as it is aimed at supporting the poor milk farmers, who manage their livelihood on the basis of their earnings from the selling of milk. However, it is important to note here that milk is an essential commodity and that the consumer will also want to buy it at any cost. Therefore, the sudden huge rate of price increase is not recommended. The rise in prices should be at a very minimal rate, which does not upset the equilibrium in the market, and also maintains the surplus of both the producers and the consumers.
Answer (C): The step taken by the Government, wherein the Government will buy all the required milk from the producers and the consumers will in turn buy the milk from the Government, does not make any substantial difference in the consumers surplus from the point of view of the consumer. The consumer is still having to the same 50% increased price for each gallon of milk. The only difference is that now the government is acting as a medium. However, from the producer’s point of view, there would be some benefit, as the producer will now not require caring about the selling of the milk, or worry about their loss, as the government will anyway buy the milk. We can assume here, that there will be a slight increase in the surplus of the producers.
Answer (d): Since the Government does nothing after fixing the price ceiling, the minimum price at which the consumer can buy a gallon of milk is $3. Now, since the milk farmers have rented their land from other land owners, the price of the land changes exogenously, and the shift I the price of land fluctuates the price of milk too. In this situation, the producer is in a better state of surplus. This is because, with the increase in the price of land, the price of milk increases highly, which is born by the consumer, however, with the decrease in the price of land, the price of milk cannot decrease below the standard $3. Therefore, the producer surplus remains all time beneficial, whereas the consumer surplus is very meager.
Answer (e): If the farmers are themselves the land owners, this would mean that the farmers are themselves able to generate and preserve all the benefits of the rise in the prices of land, and even when there is a dip in the land price, the farmer is never at a loss, as there is a price ceiling forced by the Government on the consumers. Therefore, the producer’s surplus is maximum in this scenario, whereas, the consumers are the recipients of the total negative surplus in the economy. The consumers are having to bear all the burden of the increase in the prices of land and are experiencing negative surplus from their transaction.