In: Economics
by economist Richard Thaler, “The Power of Nudges, for Good and Bad,” nudging is described as strategies that encourage consumers to buy products that they might otherwise not consider and "The Rise of the Nudge" by Tamsin Rudder describes nudges in the service of government.
a.) Provide a real life example of a "nudge" being used to encourage consumer behavior by a corporation, government or, organization that has led to improved utility or welfare of those being nudged.
b.) Explain how the nudging you cited as an example did or did not meet the other two principles of Thaler's guide for the use of nudge.
ECONOMIC VIEW
By Richard H. Thaler
Oct. 31, 2015
Nudges, small design changes that can markedly affect
individual behavior, have been catching on. These techniques rely
on insights from behavioral science, and when used ethically, they
can be very helpful. But we need to be sure that they aren’t being
employed to sway people to make bad decisions that they will later
regret.
Whenever I’m asked to autograph a copy of “Nudge,” the book
I wrote with Cass Sunstein, the Harvard law professor, I sign it,
“Nudge for good.” Unfortunately, that is meant as a plea, not an
expectation.
Three principles should guide the use of
nudges:
■ All nudging should be transparent and never
misleading.
■ It should be as easy as possible to opt out of the nudge,
preferably with as little as one mouse click.
■ There should be good reason to believe that the behavior being
encouraged will improve the welfare of those being
nudged.
As far as I know, the government teams in Britain and the United
States that have focused on nudging have followed these guidelines
scrupulously. But the private sector is another matter. In this
domain, I see much more troubling
behavior.
For example, last spring I received an email telling me
that the first prominent review of a new book of mine had appeared:
It was in The Times of London. Eager to read the review, I clicked
on a hyperlink, only to run into a pay wall. Still, I was tempted
by an offer to take out a one-month trial subscription for the
price of just £1.
As both a consumer and producer of newspaper articles, I
have no beef with pay walls. But before signing up, I read the fine
print. As expected, I would have to provide credit card information
and would be automatically enrolled as a
subscriber when the trial period expired. The subscription rate
would then be £26 (about $40) a month. That wasn’t a concern
because I did not intend to become a paying subscriber. I just
wanted to read that one article.
But the details turned me off. To cancel, I had to give 15
days’ notice, so the one-month trial offer actually was good for
just two weeks. What’s more, I would have to call London, during
British business hours, and not on a toll-free number. That was
both annoying and worrying. As an absent-minded American professor,
I figured there was a good chance I would end up subscribing for
several months, and that reading the article would end up costing
me at least £100.
I spoke to Chris Duncan, a spokesman for The Times of
London. He said his company wanted readers to call before canceling
to make sure that they appreciated the scope of the paper’s
coverage, but when I pointed out the inconvenience this posed to
readers outside Britain, he said that the company might rethink
that aspect of the
policy.
In the meantime, that deal qualifies as a nudge that
violates all three of my guiding principles: The offer was
misleading, not transparent; opting out was cumbersome; and the
entire package did not seem to be in the best interest of a
potential subscriber, as opposed to the publisher.
I ran into another type of bad nudging when I tried to book a
ticket on United Airlines to travel from Chicago to New York.
Before the airline would allow me to buy online, it required that I
indicate whether I wanted trip insurance. This sort of required
choice is justifiable when there is a genuine concern that the
consumer might make a big blunder. I would endorse posing such a
question to anyone opting out of all of an employer’s sponsored
health insurance options, for example. We wouldn’t want someone to
go without health insurance just because of a careless
oversight.
United went a step further, though. It asked me to select
“yes” or “no” before buying a ticket and highlighted the “yes”
option as “recommended.” Required choice plus a recommendation
qualifies as a strong nudge. But is it a nudge for
good?
Consider the details: The trip insurance would cost $20.13
for a flight that itself would cost only $300. Keep in mind that
the insurance covers just the nonrefundable portion of the ticket.
(Normally the charge for changing a flight on United is $200, and
the insurance would cover this.) I also learned, deep in the
fine-print weeds, that to collect on the
policy, unless the flight were canceled or delayed, I would need a
doctor’s note saying that I was too sick to fly safely, and would
have to file such documentation within 72 hours of canceling the
trip.
If my flight connected up with a cruise, the insurance
might make sense, because with the insurance I could receive
compensation when a delayed or canceled flight made me miss my
rendezvous with a cruise ship. But I wasn’t going
on a cruise.
As an alternative, I examined a fully refundable ticket,
which would cost $856. United still recommended trip insurance and
charged more for it ($49.23) even though this ticket was
refundable. Rahsaan Johnson, a United spokesman, said the company
recommended “insurance to protect against unintended expenses that
may result
from circumstances beyond the travelers’ and the airline’s
control,” but said the pricing is set by Allianz, which provides
the insurance. Daniel Durazo, an Allianz spokesman, said it priced
the insurance as a percentage of the ticket cost, but would not say
whether that formula made sense.
On the positive side, opting out of these offers was easy,
but the nudges flunked my other tests: They were neither
transparent nor in the best interest of most
customers.
These examples are not unusual. Many companies are nudging
purely for their own profit and not in customers’ best interests.
In a recent column in The New York Times, Robert Shiller called
such behavior “phishing.” Mr. Shiller and George Akerlof, both
Nobel-winning economists, have written a book on the subject,
“Phishing for Phools.”
Some argue that phishing — or evil nudging — is more
dangerous in government than in the private sector. The argument is
that government is a monopoly with coercive power, while we have
more choice in the private sector over which newspapers we read and
which airlines we fly.
I think this distinction is overstated. In a democracy, if
a government creates bad policies, it can be voted out of office.
Competition in the private sector, however, can easily work to
encourage phishing rather than stifle it.
One example is the mortgage industry in the early 2000s. Borrowers were encouraged to take out loans that they could not repay when real estate prices fell. Competition did not eliminate this practice, because it was hard for anyone to make money selling the advice “Don’t take that loan.”
As customers, we can help one another by resisting these
come-ons. The more we turn down questionable offers like trip
insurance and scrutinize “one month” trials, the less incentive
companies will have to use such schemes.
Conversely, if customers reward firms that act in our best
interests, more such outfits will survive and flourish, and the
options available to us will improve.
a) A real life example of a nudge being used to encourage consumer behavior by several corporations around the world is that of charging money for the use of a plastic bag, when one checks out of a store, in order to discourage the use of plastic bags. It is observed in several supermarket chains, utility stores, etc. Thus ultimately it is the consumers who are benefiting from such a nudge as the level of pollution in an economy is drastically reduced and it is encouraging consumer behavior of being conservatory and enhancing the utility of old bags which are easily recyclable.
b) The nudging was transparent meaning the cashier's always mentioned whether one wants a bag and that the bag is chargeable. Thus it was never misleading, however in some stores there were employees who tried to automatically give a bag and charged it to the bill without informing the customer. Thus there are certain cases where employees forget to mention but it is not always the case as the customer is also aware of the extra charge and doesn't need a nudge all the time.
It is very easy to opt out of paying for a plastic bag by saying no, or by choosing ourselves at the check out counters that I don't want a plastic bag and most of the supermarket chains and other utilities have that option of easily opting out of payment.