In: Economics
Read the July 9, 2006 the Freakonomics column in the New York Times Magazine uploaded in the docs and stuff section of this site. The authors examine a simple supply-and-demand gap with tragic implications: the shortage of human organs for transplantation. In the space of just a few decades, transplant surgery has become remarkably safe and reliable. But this success has bred huge demand: as more patients get new organs, more patients want them. So, while the number of kidney transplants has risen by 45% in the past 10 years, the number of people on a kidney waiting list has risen by 119%. Consequently, some 3,500 people die each year while waiting for a kidney transplant. A big problem is that would-be suppliers of kidneys, whether living or dead, are not given very strong incentives to step forward.
1. Summarize the main arguments about providing incentives for the supply side of this volunteer market.
2. Evaluate the argument carefully. What do you think? Why?
July 9, 2006
Freakonomics
Flesh Trade
By STEPHEN J. DUBNER and STEVEN D. LEVITT
Weighing the Repugnance Factor
How's this for a repugnant situation? Take someone you love,
perhaps your spouse or your sibling, and find a stranger who will
accept a really big bet that your loved one will die prematurely —
and if indeed that happens, you pocket a few million dollars.
This, of course, is how life insurance works. And most Americans
don't find this idea repugnant at all. They used to, however. Until
the mid-19th century, life insurance was considered "a
profanation," as the sociologist Viviana Zelizer has written,
"which transformed the sacred event of death into a vulgar
commodity."
Alvin Roth, a Harvard economist who studies the design of markets,
has done a lot of thinking about repugnance. On some issues, he
notes, repugnance will recede, as with life insurance — or, even
more momentously, the practice of charging interest on loans. In
other cases, the reverse happens: a once-accepted behavior like
slaveholding comes to be seen as repugnant.
One case of repugnance is far from settled: the dispute over how
human organs for transplantation should be allocated — and,
perhaps, even sold. If you happen to have a failing heart or liver
or kidneys, you will almost certainly die without a transplant, but
if you aren't lucky enough to get an organ through an official
registry, you can't legally purchase one at any price. So instead
of a free market in organs, we have a volunteer market. Some people
agree to give up their usable organs once they die. In the case of
a living donor, someone sacrifices a kidney or a portion of a liver
to a recipient, most likely a family member.
In the space of just a few decades, transplant surgery has become
safe and reliable (to say nothing of miraculous). But success
breeds demand: as more patients get new organs, more patients want
them. In 2005, more than 16,000 kidney transplants were performed
in the U.S., an increase of 45 percent over 10 years. But during
that time, the number of people on a kidney waiting list rose by
119 percent. More than 3,500 people now die each year waiting for a
kidney transplant.
To an economist, this is a basic supply-and-demand gap with tragic
consequences. So what can be done to increase the supply of
organs?
A big problem is that would-be suppliers are not given very strong
incentives to step forward. In much of Europe, the choice is made
for them: instead of "opting in" to donate, the default assumption
is that your usable organs will be harvested upon your death unless
your family "opts out." But Europe, too, still has a sizable organ
shortage, in part because traffic fatalities — which tend to
produce desirable organs for harvest — are on a downward trend in
Western countries.
If it's hard to get people to give up their organs upon death,
consider how much harder it is to persuade a living person to
donate a kidney. (From a medical perspective, a kidney from a
living donor is far more valuable than a cadaver kidney.) Even
though most people can live safely on one kidney, there is still a
price to be paid in discomfort, risk, fear and lost wages. But the
United States, like pretty much every other country in the world,
forbids a donor to collect on that price, or any other.
It is hard to find an economist who agrees with this policy. Gary
Becker and Julio Jorge Elias argued in a recent paper that
"monetary incentives would increase the supply of organs for
transplant sufficiently to eliminate the very large queues in organ
markets, and the suffering and deaths of many of those waiting,
without increasing the total cost of transplant surgery by more
than 12 percent."
Some noneconomists may well find this reasoning repugnant. There
are many reasons, after all, for banning the sale of organs. Some
people consider it immoral to commodify body parts (although it is
now commonplace to not only sell sperm and eggs but also to rent a
womb). Others fear that most organ sellers would be poor while most
buyers would be rich; or that someone might be pressured into
selling a kidney without fully understanding the risks.
But why, Becker and Elias ask, should poor people "be deprived of
revenue that could be highly useful to them"? Even more compelling
is the fact that a poor person is just as likely as a wealthy
person (if not more so) to need a new kidney — and, with no legal
market for organs, is just as likely to die while waiting on a
list.
Alvin Roth, even though he is an economist, is smart enough to
realize that repugnance will keep Americans from embracing a true
market for organs anytime soon. So, along with several other
scholars and medical personnel, he has helped design a clever
alternative, the New England Program for Kidney Exchange. Imagine
that you have a wife who is dying of renal failure, and that you
would give her one of your kidneys, but you are not a biological
match. Now imagine that another couple is in the same bind. The
kidney exchange locates and matches the couples: you donate your
kidney to the stranger's wife, while the stranger gives his kidney
to your wife; the operations are performed simultaneously to make
sure no one backs out. Although this system has yielded only a
couple dozen transplants so far, it illustrates an economist's
understanding of incentives: if you can't get someone to give an
organ out of altruism, and you can't pay him either, what do you
do? Find two parties who are desperate to align their
incentives.
Otherwise, who in his right mind would step forward to donate a
kidney to a stranger? In fact, we recently spoke to one such
potential donor who asked to remain anonymous. Donor is married,
with four children and a precarious financial situation. Because
Donor had a sibling who nearly needed an organ transplant, the idea
got into Donor's head to perhaps sell a kidney to a stranger.
Through a donor Web site, Donor met a potential recipient, whom
we'll call Recipient. It wasn't until the process was well under
way that Donor learned it was illegal to be paid. In the end,
however, Donor's moral mission overrode the financial need, and
Donor decided to go ahead with the transplant.
Donor has undergone extensive testing at the hospital where
Recipient will have the transplant. Both Donor and Recipient have
had to lie repeatedly to the doctors, pretending they are old
friends. "If they find out you met on the Internet," Donor
explains, "they assume it's for money, and they'll call off the
operation."
If all goes well, the transplant may happen soon. Consider the
parties who stand to profit from this transaction: Recipient,
certainly, as well as the transplant surgeons, the nurses, the
hospital, the drug companies. Everyone will be paid in some form —
except for Donor, who not only isn't being paid but, in return for
carrying out a deeply altruistic act, also has to pay the
additional price of lying about it.
Surely there are some people, and not just economists, who would
find this situation — well, repugnant.
1) Some people who are willing donating there organs after their death is motivated or encouraged that after their death they will be able to help some or other in any way by donating organs. Where as donating organs willingly is legal and donating by taking money is illegal. There are also cases where people donate willingly even while living those are mostly in case of family members.
People in all these cases are motivated by either money or relationships or for helping people. These are main scenarios we can see in this supply market.
2) From the above argument we can come to a conclusion that due to improvement in technology organ transplantation is becoming easy these days.
People are donating organs are motivated by either money or relationships or for helping people. These are main scenarios we can see in this supply market.
The main problem arises that people who are taking money for donating should be banned becuase these are illegal and is like trying to get their needs by donating some organs where they dont die by donating. If the officials come to know about these things they are going put both the donor and recepient in jail. So people are trying to cover by saying that they are family or close friends. So Doctors should take care while attending these cases and do a thorough back ground check.