Question

In: Economics

Read the July 9, 2006 the Freakonomics column in the New York Times Magazine uploaded in...

Read the July 9, 2006 the Freakonomics column in the New York Times Magazine uploaded in the docs and stuff section of this site. The authors examine a simple supply-and-demand gap with tragic implications: the shortage of human organs for transplantation. In the space of just a few decades, transplant surgery has become remarkably safe and reliable. But this success has bred huge demand: as more patients get new organs, more patients want them. So, while the number of kidney transplants has risen by 45% in the past 10 years, the number of people on a kidney waiting list has risen by 119%. Consequently, some 3,500 people die each year while waiting for a kidney transplant. A big problem is that would-be suppliers of kidneys, whether living or dead, are not given very strong incentives to step forward.

1. Summarize the main arguments about providing incentives for the supply side of this volunteer market.

2. Evaluate the argument carefully. What do you think? Why?

July 9, 2006
Freakonomics
Flesh Trade
By STEPHEN J. DUBNER and STEVEN D. LEVITT
Weighing the Repugnance Factor

How's this for a repugnant situation? Take someone you love, perhaps your spouse or your sibling, and find a stranger who will accept a really big bet that your loved one will die prematurely — and if indeed that happens, you pocket a few million dollars.

This, of course, is how life insurance works. And most Americans don't find this idea repugnant at all. They used to, however. Until the mid-19th century, life insurance was considered "a profanation," as the sociologist Viviana Zelizer has written, "which transformed the sacred event of death into a vulgar commodity."

Alvin Roth, a Harvard economist who studies the design of markets, has done a lot of thinking about repugnance. On some issues, he notes, repugnance will recede, as with life insurance — or, even more momentously, the practice of charging interest on loans. In other cases, the reverse happens: a once-accepted behavior like slaveholding comes to be seen as repugnant.

One case of repugnance is far from settled: the dispute over how human organs for transplantation should be allocated — and, perhaps, even sold. If you happen to have a failing heart or liver or kidneys, you will almost certainly die without a transplant, but if you aren't lucky enough to get an organ through an official registry, you can't legally purchase one at any price. So instead of a free market in organs, we have a volunteer market. Some people agree to give up their usable organs once they die. In the case of a living donor, someone sacrifices a kidney or a portion of a liver to a recipient, most likely a family member.
In the space of just a few decades, transplant surgery has become safe and reliable (to say nothing of miraculous). But success breeds demand: as more patients get new organs, more patients want them. In 2005, more than 16,000 kidney transplants were performed in the U.S., an increase of 45 percent over 10 years. But during that time, the number of people on a kidney waiting list rose by 119 percent. More than 3,500 people now die each year waiting for a kidney transplant.

To an economist, this is a basic supply-and-demand gap with tragic consequences. So what can be done to increase the supply of organs?

A big problem is that would-be suppliers are not given very strong incentives to step forward. In much of Europe, the choice is made for them: instead of "opting in" to donate, the default assumption is that your usable organs will be harvested upon your death unless your family "opts out." But Europe, too, still has a sizable organ shortage, in part because traffic fatalities — which tend to produce desirable organs for harvest — are on a downward trend in Western countries.
If it's hard to get people to give up their organs upon death, consider how much harder it is to persuade a living person to donate a kidney. (From a medical perspective, a kidney from a living donor is far more valuable than a cadaver kidney.) Even though most people can live safely on one kidney, there is still a price to be paid in discomfort, risk, fear and lost wages. But the United States, like pretty much every other country in the world, forbids a donor to collect on that price, or any other.

It is hard to find an economist who agrees with this policy. Gary Becker and Julio Jorge Elias argued in a recent paper that "monetary incentives would increase the supply of organs for transplant sufficiently to eliminate the very large queues in organ markets, and the suffering and deaths of many of those waiting, without increasing the total cost of transplant surgery by more than 12 percent."

Some noneconomists may well find this reasoning repugnant. There are many reasons, after all, for banning the sale of organs. Some people consider it immoral to commodify body parts (although it is now commonplace to not only sell sperm and eggs but also to rent a womb). Others fear that most organ sellers would be poor while most buyers would be rich; or that someone might be pressured into selling a kidney without fully understanding the risks.

But why, Becker and Elias ask, should poor people "be deprived of revenue that could be highly useful to them"? Even more compelling is the fact that a poor person is just as likely as a wealthy person (if not more so) to need a new kidney — and, with no legal market for organs, is just as likely to die while waiting on a list.

Alvin Roth, even though he is an economist, is smart enough to realize that repugnance will keep Americans from embracing a true market for organs anytime soon. So, along with several other scholars and medical personnel, he has helped design a clever alternative, the New England Program for Kidney Exchange. Imagine that you have a wife who is dying of renal failure, and that you would give her one of your kidneys, but you are not a biological match. Now imagine that another couple is in the same bind. The kidney exchange locates and matches the couples: you donate your kidney to the stranger's wife, while the stranger gives his kidney to your wife; the operations are performed simultaneously to make sure no one backs out. Although this system has yielded only a couple dozen transplants so far, it illustrates an economist's understanding of incentives: if you can't get someone to give an organ out of altruism, and you can't pay him either, what do you do? Find two parties who are desperate to align their incentives.

Otherwise, who in his right mind would step forward to donate a kidney to a stranger? In fact, we recently spoke to one such potential donor who asked to remain anonymous. Donor is married, with four children and a precarious financial situation. Because Donor had a sibling who nearly needed an organ transplant, the idea got into Donor's head to perhaps sell a kidney to a stranger. Through a donor Web site, Donor met a potential recipient, whom we'll call Recipient. It wasn't until the process was well under way that Donor learned it was illegal to be paid. In the end, however, Donor's moral mission overrode the financial need, and Donor decided to go ahead with the transplant.
Donor has undergone extensive testing at the hospital where Recipient will have the transplant. Both Donor and Recipient have had to lie repeatedly to the doctors, pretending they are old friends. "If they find out you met on the Internet," Donor explains, "they assume it's for money, and they'll call off the operation."

If all goes well, the transplant may happen soon. Consider the parties who stand to profit from this transaction: Recipient, certainly, as well as the transplant surgeons, the nurses, the hospital, the drug companies. Everyone will be paid in some form — except for Donor, who not only isn't being paid but, in return for carrying out a deeply altruistic act, also has to pay the additional price of lying about it.

Surely there are some people, and not just economists, who would find this situation — well, repugnant.

Solutions

Expert Solution

1) Some people who are willing donating there organs after their death is motivated or encouraged that after their death they will be able to help some or other in any way by donating organs. Where as donating organs willingly is legal and donating by taking money is illegal. There are also cases where people donate willingly even while living those are mostly in case of family members.

People in all these cases are motivated by either money or relationships or for helping people. These are main scenarios we can see in this supply market.

2) From the above argument we can come to a conclusion that due to improvement in technology organ transplantation is becoming easy these days.

People are donating organs are motivated by either money or relationships or for helping people. These are main scenarios we can see in this supply market.

The main problem arises that people who are taking money for donating should be banned becuase these are illegal and is like trying to get their needs by donating some organs where they dont die by donating. If the officials come to know about these things they are going put both the donor and recepient in jail. So people are trying to cover by saying that they are family or close friends. So Doctors should take care while attending these cases and do a thorough back ground check.


Related Solutions

as reported by runner’s world magazine, the times of the finishers in the new york city...
as reported by runner’s world magazine, the times of the finishers in the new york city 10-km run are normally distributed with a mean of 61 minutes and a standard deviation of 9 minutes. Let X denote the time of a randonly selected finisher. Find P[43<X<70]. Round your answer to three decimal points.
As reported in Runner’s World magazine, the times of the finishers in the New York City...
As reported in Runner’s World magazine, the times of the finishers in the New York City 10-km run are normally distributed with mean 61 minutes and standard deviation 9 minutes. a.Determine the percentage of finishers who have times between 50 and 70 minutes. b. Obtain and interpret the 40th percentile for the finishing times. c. Find the middle 30% of the finishing times.
1. As reported in Runners World magazine, the times of the finishers in the New York...
1. As reported in Runners World magazine, the times of the finishers in the New York City 10 km run follow the normal model with mean=61 minutes and standard deviation= 9 minutes. a) Using the 68-95-99.7% rule, 68% of runners will finsh between which two times? (In minutes) b) Using the 68-95-99.7% rule, 99.7% of runners will finish between which two times? (In minutes) Use z-scores and your z-table for the following. Round z-scores to two decimal places but give...
As reported in "Runner's World" magazine, the times of the finishers in the New York City...
As reported in "Runner's World" magazine, the times of the finishers in the New York City 10 km run are normally distributed with a mean of 61 minutes and a standard deviation of 9 minutes. Let x denote finishing time for the finishers. a) The distribution of the variable x has mean____ and standard deviation____ . b) The distribution of the standardized variable z has mean____ and standard deviation____ . c) The percentage of finishers with times between 60 and...
A column in the New York Times noted that during the housing boom that ended in...
A column in the New York Times noted that during the housing boom that ended in 2006: open double quote“Global banks had loaded up on these supposedly safe securities, and were at risk of becoming insolvent when their true value became known. Some banks blew up; others were bailed out. Source: Neil Irwin, open double quote“What 'The Big Short' Gets Right, and Wrong, About the Housing Bubble, close double quote” New York Times ,December  22, 2015. Which of the following are...
A column in the New York Times in 2017 was titled “The Low-Inflation World May Be...
A column in the New York Times in 2017 was titled “The Low-Inflation World May Be Sticking Around Longer Than Expected.” Are the low inflation rates of recent years entirely the result of Federal Reserve policy? Could they have occurred without the Fed having a mandate to achieve price stability? Briefly explain.
1. Nobel Prize–winning economist Milton Friedman stated in a New York Times Magazine article in 1970...
1. Nobel Prize–winning economist Milton Friedman stated in a New York Times Magazine article in 1970 that the only “social responsibility of a business is to increase its profits.” Using the stakeholder theory and corporate examples, please explain if this statement is right or wrong in today's business environment. 2. What are the big ethical dilemmas of the twenty-first century? Please discuss a corporate example facing ethical dilemmas regarding its consumers.
Read the article “Nintendo Slashes U.S. Price of GameCube,” published in the New York Times, September...
Read the article “Nintendo Slashes U.S. Price of GameCube,” published in the New York Times, September 24, 2003. What type of price discrimination was applied by the company? What were the available conditions that made the discrimination possible?
11-37) A headline in The New York Times on August 16, 2017 read: “Hartford (Connecticut), with...
11-37) A headline in The New York Times on August 16, 2017 read: “Hartford (Connecticut), with Finances in Disarray, Veers Toward Bankruptcy.” The article said, among other things, “...Hartford, which has one of the highest property tax rates in the state … still cannot raise enough money to pay for basic government operations.” Here are some economic, demographic, and financial data taken Census Bureau QuickFacts (accessed August, 2017) and from Hartford’s June 30, 2016 CAFR. (The financial statements, expressed in...
In his New York Times column of May 27, 2005, economist Paul Krugman stated: “After all,...
In his New York Times column of May 27, 2005, economist Paul Krugman stated: “After all, the Fed’s ability to manage the economy mainly comes from its ability to create booms and busts in the housing market.” What do you think he meant by that statement? Is it an accurate characterization of the Federal Reserve’s influence over the real economy?
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT
ADVERTISEMENT