In: Economics
Describe the two primary models of exchange rate determination using equations, narrative, and graphs, as necessary.
1) The Balance of Trade as a Determinant of Exchange Rates The
BOP theory views exchange rates as determined in flow markets.
Recall that we want to determine equilibrium exchange rates. The
balance of trade approach simplifies the BOP approach. In this
context, exchange rates will move to eliminate international trade
imbalances. To simplify the theory, assume that the KA and OR are
equal to zero. In this case, the BOP is equal to the CA. The
current account is determined by the difference between exports (X)
and imports (M). Both exports and imports are a function of the
real exchange rate (Rt), domestic income (Yd) and foreign income
(Yf). Therefore, CA = X - M = f(Rt, Yd,Yf). In general, at higher
real exchange rates we should expect more exports and fewer
imports, and higher current account surpluses; while at lower real
exchange rates, the opposite should occur.
According to the balance of trade approach, the exchange rate moves
in the required direction to compensate a trade imbalance. For
example, suppose the trade balance is in equilibrium –i.e., CA=0.
An increase in domestic income leads to an increase in demand for
imports and therefore to a trade deficit (CA<0). Then, we should
expect the exchange rate to depreciate to correct this imbalance.
Using a similar argument, we should also expect a depreciation of
the domestic currency, following an increase in domestic prices, a
decrease in foreign prices, or a decrease in foreign income.
Example IV.3: The drop in oil prices after the Gulf War led to a
Venezuelan trade balance deficit; the value of the oil that
Venezuela exported suddenly dropped, without a corresponding
reduction in imports. This deficit forced the Venezuelan government
to borrow abroad to offset the imbalance; it also led to a
depreciation of the bolivar. This devaluation helped to equilibrate
the CA. ¶ The balance of trade approach needs the estimation of
trade elasticities with respect to changes in exchange rates. These
elasticities are needed to measure the response of imports and
exports to a change in exchange rates. To calculate the
elasticities we need to distinguish between short-run elasticities
and long-run elasticities. For example, because of contracts, in
the short-run imports and exports are quite inelastic (insensitive)
to changes in exchange rates. Then, contrary to what the balance of
trade approach predicts, in the short-run, a devaluation might
increase the CA imbalance. Over time, however, we should expect
this CA imbalance to be reversed. This over-time phenomenon of the
CA is called the J-curve. During the past twenty years, it has
become quite clear that exchange rates did not work in the simple
way considered by the balance of trade approach. There have been
many situations when countries with trade surpluses have
depreciating currencies, while countries with trade deficits have
appreciating currencies.
2) The Absorption Approach to the Balance of Trade The
absorption approach to the balance of trade (CA) studies how
domestic spending on domestic goods changes relative to domestic
output. That is, the CA is viewed as the difference between what
the economy produces and what it consumes, or absorbs, for domestic
purposes. Using basic macroeconomic identities, in equilibrium, we
can write Y = C + I + G –T + (X - M), where C is consumption, I is
private investment, G is government spending and T is national
taxes. Absorption, A, is defined as the sum of C+I+G. If total
output, Y, exceeds absorption, A, then the nation will export more
to the rest of the world and the current account will increase. On
the other hand, if absorption exceeds domestic output, the current
account will fall. The absorption approach can analyze the effect
of a devaluation on the trade balance. For example, if a government
devalues its currency, a devaluation would tend to increase net
exports and, then, domestic output only if the economy is not at
the full employment level. If the economy is at the full employment
level a devaluation will only result in inflationary
pressures.
Rearranging terms in the previous equation, CA = S - [I + (G - T)],
where S is after-tax private savings. Now, we can analyze how to
reduce a CA deficit. To increase the CA, one of the following must
happen: (1) S should be increased, for a given level of I and
(G-T). (2) I must fall, for a given level of S and (G-T). (3) The
government deficit G-T must fall, for a given level of S and I.
Example IV.4: As a country, Japan has a high savings rate relative
to the rest of the world. Many argue that this is the reason behind
the persistent Japanese CA surpluses. One of the usual proposed
solutions to reduce the persistent Japanese CA surplus is to
increase the size of the Japanese government spending. ¶ The
absorption approach helps us to understand the balance of trade.
But this theory will only work as a theory of the BOP in a world
without capital flows.