In: Economics
1. Diamond makes an argument that all stratified societies employ one (or a combination) of four means to enable and justify the distribution of the social surplus. From the readings, discuss feudal stratification and how it was enabled and justified.
2. The basic economic ideology concerning market activity in Feudal times arose from the Church. What did the church consider sinful or acceptable regarding economic activity and why?
1) Historically, societies have exhibited a varied range of stratification systems. A stratification system is the overlapping manner in which societal members are ranked into classes, status groups and hierarchies of power. In order to distinguish among them, social scientists often use models, abstract conceptions that they place on a particular continuum. At one extreme of the continuum is the closed, or caste, stratification system. The middle is represented by the estate system. At the other extreme is the open, or class, system.
The Closed Society: Caste
Whether a society has an open or a closed stratification system
is determined by the way its members obtain wealth, prestige and
privilege. In a closed, or caste, stratification
system, class, status and power are ascribed, that is,
determined strictly on the basis of family inheritance rather than
individual effort or merit. In a closed society, the individual is
born into a specific social stratum, called a
caste, and has no opportunity to move in or out of
it.
The Estate System
The estate system was the economic and social system that
prevailed in feudal Europe and, existed in different forms, has
characterized a number of nations in Asia. As in the caste system,
in the estate system of stratification, social
positions were also ranked according to their functions; however,
in theory, all the estates were considered equal in importance. The
three main estates were: (i) the nobility, (ii) the church
(religion) and (iii) the peasants, and within each estate there was
a stratified hierarchy of positions.
Supported by religion and tradition, the estate system permitted
quite a bit more mobility among social strata than did the caste
system. Because only eldest sons could inherit the title and
possessions of a noble family, the remaining sons had to enter
either the military or the clergy. Occasionally, serfs who had
distinguished themselves were freed and given land, and some
peasants were allowed to enter the lower ranks of the priesthood.
The remnants of the estate system are still visible in some modern
societies that retain a landed gentry and inherited titles of
nobility.
The Open Society: Class System
Modern industrial and postindustrial societies mostly nearly approximate the model of an open society. Open, or class, societies have a few common characteristics:
Open, or class, systems work best in industrial societies that have market economics, because these offer more opportunities for achieving wealth and status than do societies with centralized economies. In government-controlled economies, people may not have the opportunity to choose their jobs and maximize advantages.
Social mobility – essentially, changing class membership – is
possible and encouraged in open systems; however, it is not evenly
distributed in the society. Limitations based on racial, ethnic,
regional, educational and even religious factors restrict mobility.
However, the individual is still permitted much more leeway for
social as well as physical movement than in closed systems.
2) Feudalism is a medieval model of Government which predated the
birth of modern nation state. It was a term for system of political
and social order in Medieval Western Europe
i)New economic pattern based on land ownership
ii)The manor became the main economic unit.
iii)Feudal system developed
iv)King at top
v)Lords, vassals, and peasants
Like all pre-industrial societies, medieval Europe had a
predominantly agricultural economy. The basic economic unit was the
manor, managed by its lord and his officials. This was, in the
early Middle Ages especially, a largely self-sufficient farming
estate, with its peasant inhabitants growing their own crops,
keeping their own cattle, making their own bread, cheese, beer or
wine, and as far as possible making and repairing their own
equipment, clothes, cottages, furniture and all the necessities of
life.
Surplus produce was sold at the nearest market town, where
equipment which could not be made or maintained in the manor
workshops, or luxuries unavailable locally, could be purchased.
Here craftsmen and shopkeepers such as cobblers, tailors,
costermongers, tinkers, smiths and others plied their trades.
The medieval Roman Catholic Church, as an economic and political
entity, attempted to accomplish its otherworldly goals in this
world by acquiring power and influence. Most large corporations
need access to capital markets to grow and prosper. The medieval
Church was no exception, but it was constrained by its own
admonitions against “laying up earthly treasure” and “serving
Mammon instead of God.” This article discusses the political
economy of the medieval Church, focusing on its response to the
Crusades and also considering purgatory, indulgences, and the
Protestant Reformation, as well as marriage as a sacrament.
The Roman Church held monarchs and other secular leaders at bay for
several reasons. The papacy was a monopoly in the competition for
power—a monopoly possibly dating as far back as Charlemagne—against
monarchs and feudal lords. But most important, polities in the
medieval period were at the mercy of the Roman Christian monopoly
over the supernatural belief system. Rome’s approbation of a
secular leader meant support by his or her subjects. The Church was
able to use Christianity and particular doctrinal innovations as
weapons to receive benefits in its dealings with both Church
members and in the secular political world.
By its nature, monopolistic behavior has important economic
consequences. Social scientists working in the field of religion
therefore face the following uncomfortable circumstance: although
its stated goals were spiritual, the medieval Roman Catholic Church
functioned in large measure as an economic and political firm,
making decisions about the nature and characteristics of its
“product” as well as establishing the organizational structure to
provide that product—with various quality assurances—to its
customers, the religious faithful. In other words, the Catholic
Church could not help but be a key economic and political player in
the medieval world. The ultimate consequence of this behavior was
the successful entry by Protestants in the early sixteenth
century.
Material wealth was seen as necessary, since with out it a man
could not support his family or help his neighbors. But it must be
stressed that wealth was a means to an end, not an end in itself,
and a man should have no more wealth than he required. Unlike
modern society which accepts profit growth as justification for
almost any action, the medieval world considered economic actions
subordinate to moral authority. "The Church condemned as a sin
precisely that effort to achieve a continuous and unlimited
increase in material wealth which modern society upholds as a
virtue."