In: Economics
1. True or false- In the Keynesian model, the predictions will remain the same and it does not depend on what the initial economy was like. In the AD/AS model, what the initial economy was like does matter because predictions are different for those that are near full employment than for those that are below full employment.
A)True
B) False
2. In the Ad/as model, what does it say about adjustment?
a) economy adjusts when it is in the long run
b) government can intervene
c) in the short run, the economy can be less than full employment
d) This model states that the adjustments are between classical/Keynesian interpretations.
e) All of these are correct.
3) The predictions for the AD/AS model are -------of the Keynesian models when the economy is in recession.
a)same
b)similar
c)different
d) the AD/AS model doesn't use predictions
e) the keynesian model doesn't use predictions.
4) If the economy is in a good place, predictions of the Ad/as model are_______of the Keynesian odel
a)same
b) Keynsian model doesn't have predictions
c)Ad/as doesn't have predictions
d) different
e) similar
1. False.
KEY NOTES
Aggregate demand is the sum of four components: consumption, investment, government spending, and net exports.
Consumption can change for a number of reasons, including movements in income, taxes, expectations about future income, and changes in wealth levels.
Investment can change in response to its expected profitability, which in turn is shaped by expectations about future economic growth, the creation of new technologies, the price of key inputs, and tax incentives for investment. Investment can also change when interest rates rise or fall.
Government spending and taxes are determined by political considerations.
Exports and imports change according to relative growth rates and prices between two economies.
Disposable income is income after taxes.
An inflationary gap exists when equilibrium is at a level of output above potential GDP.
A recessionary gap exists when equilibrium is at a level of output below potential GDP.
Aggregate demand in Keynesian analysis
The Keynesian perspective focuses on aggregate demand. The general idea being that firms produce output only if they expect it to sell.
Thus, while the availability of the factors of production determines a nation’s potential gross domestic product, or GDP, the amount of goods and services actually being sold—known as real GDP—depends on how much demand exists across the economy. You can see this concept represented graphically in the diagram below.
This Keynesian view of the AD/AS model shows that with a horizontal aggregate supply, a decrease in demand leads to a decrease in output but no decrease in prices.
Keynes argued that, for reasons we'll explain shortly, aggregate demand is not stable—it can change unexpectedly.
Suppose the economy starts where \text{AD0}AD0intersects \text{SRAS}SRAS at \text{P0}P0 and \text{Yp}Yp in the diagram above. Because \text{Yp}Yp is potential output, the economy is at full employment. But because aggregate demand is volatile, it can easily fall. Thus, even if we start at \text{Yp}Yp, if aggregate demand falls, we find ourselves in what Keynes termed a recessionary gap. The economy is in equilibrium but with less than full employment, as shown at \text{Y1}Y1. Keynes believed that the economy would tend to stay in a recessionary gap, with its attendant unemployment, for a significant period of time.
Similarly—though not shown in the figure—if aggregate demand increases, the economy could experience an inflationary gap, where demand is attempting to push the economy past potential output. As a consequence, the economy would experience inflation.
The key policy implication for either situation is that government needs to step in and close the gap, increasing spending during recessions and decreasing spending during booms, to return aggregate demand to match potential output.
Since aggregate demand is total spending, economy-wide, on domestic goods and services, economists also refer to it as total planned expenditure. We can calculate aggregate demand by adding up its four components: consumption expenditure, investment expenditure, government spending, and spending on net exports—exports minus imports.
2. e.
Key points
The aggregate demand/aggregate supply, or AD/AS, model is one of the fundamental tools in economics because it provides an overall framework for bringing economic factors together in one diagram.
We can examine long-run economic growth using the AD/AS model, but the factors that determine the speed of this long-term economic growth rate do not appear directly in the AD/AS diagram.
Cyclical unemployment is relatively large in the AD/AS framework when the equilibrium is substantially below potential GDP and relatively small when the equilibrium is near potential GDP.
The natural rate of unemployment—as determined by the labor market institutions of the economy—is built into potential GDP, but does not otherwise appear in an AD/AS diagram.
Pressures for inflation to rise or fall are shown in the AD/AS framework when the movement from one equilibrium to another causes the price level to rise or to fall.
The AD/AS model allows economists to analyze multiple economic factors.
Macroeconomics takes an overall view of the economy, which means that it needs to juggle many different concepts including the three macroeconomic goals of growth, low inflation, and low unemployment; the elements of aggregate demand; aggregate supply; and a wide array of economic events and policy decisions.
The aggregate demand/aggregate supply, or AD/AS, model is one of the fundamental tools in economics because it provides an overall framework for bringing these factors together in one diagram. In addition, the AD/AS framework is flexible enough to accommodate both the Keynes’ law approach—focusing on aggregate demand and the short run—while also including the Say’s law approach—focusing on aggregate supply and the long run.
Growth and recession in the AD/AS model
We can examine both long-term and short-term changes in gross domestic product, or GDP, using the AD/AS model. In an AD/AS diagram, long-run economic growth due to productivity increases over time is represented by a gradual rightward shift of aggregate supply. The vertical line representing potential GDP—the full-employment level of gross domestic product—gradually shifts to the right over time as well. You can see this effect in AD/AS diagram A below, which shows a pattern of economic growth over three years.
However, the factors that determine the speed of this long-term economic growth rate—like investment in physical and human capital, technology, and whether an economy can take advantage of catch-up growth—do not appear directly in an AD/AS diagram.
In the short run, GDP, falls and rises in every economy as the economy dips into recession or expands out of recession. When an AD/AS diagram shows an equilibrium level of real GDP substantially below potential GDP—as is shown in the diagram below at equilibrium point \text{E0}E0—it indicates a recession. On the other hand, in years of resurgent economic growth the equilibrium will typically be close to potential GDP—as it is at equilibrium point \text{E1}E1.
Unemployment in the AD/AS diagram
We can examine two different types of unemployment using an AD/AS diagram—cyclical unemployment and the natural rate of unemployment. Cyclical unemployment bounces up and down according to the short-run movements of GDP. The long-term, baseline level of unemployment that occurs year in and year out, however, is called the natural rate of unemployment.
The natural rate of unemployment is determined by how well the structures of market and government institutions in the economy lead to a matching of workers and employers in the labor market. Potential GDP can imply different unemployment rates in different economies, depending on the natural rate of unemployment for that economy.
In an AD/AS diagram, cyclical unemployment is shown by how close the economy is to the potential or full-employment level of GDP. Take another look at the AD/AS diagram above. Relatively low cyclical unemployment for an economy occurs when the level of output is close to potential GDP, as at the equilibrium point \text{E1}E1. On the other hand, high cyclical unemployment arises when the output is substantially to the left of potential GDP on the AD/AS diagram, as at the equilibrium point \text{E0}E0.
The factors that determine the natural rate of unemployment are not shown separately in the AD/AS model, although they are implicitly part of what determines potential GDP, or full-employment GDP, in a given economy.
Inflationary pressures in the AD/AS diagram
Inflation fluctuates in the short run, and higher inflation rates typically occur either during or just after economic booms. For example, the biggest spurts of inflation in the US economy during the 20th century followed the wartime booms of World War I and World War II. On the other hand, rates of inflation generally decline during recessions.
The AD/AS framework implies two ways that inflationary pressures may arise. One possible trigger is if aggregate demand continues to shift to the right when the economy is already at or near potential GDP and full employment, thus pushing the macroeconomic equilibrium into the steep portion of the aggregate supply curve. Let's look at diagram A, on the left below. In this diagram, you'll see a shift of aggregate demand to the right. The new equilibrium \text{E1}E1 is at a higher price level than the original equilibrium \text{E0}E0. In this situation, the aggregate demand in the economy has soared so high that firms in the economy are not capable of producing additional goods because labor and physical capital are fully employed, and so additional increases in aggregate demand can only result in a rise in the price level.
Another source of inflationary pressures is a rise in input prices that affects many or most firms across the economy—perhaps an important input to production like oil or labor. This situation can cause the aggregate supply curve to shift back to the left. In diagram B above, the shift of the SRAS curve to the left also increases the price level from \text{P0}P0 at the original equilibrium \text{E0}E0 to a higher price level of \text{P1}P1 at the new equilibrium \text{E1}E1. In effect, the rise in input prices ends up—after the final output is produced and sold—being passed along in the form of a higher price level for outputs.
3.b. A described previously in 1st questions' answer.
4.a