This article illustrates the political economy of international
trade and the concept of comparative advantage. Explain Who are the
"Winners" and "Losers" and why as described in this article, and
the effect of "arbitrary government intervention" that circumvents
the workings of free trade initiated by Senator Trent Lott as
described in the article? Use the economic concept of comparative
advantage in your explanation. (10 points). Due Jun 27 As a side
note - why do a number of popular Maryland Restaurants advertise
they only serve Maryland Crabmeat in their crab cakes??????? Check
out the web site for the McConnell et al - Microeconomics 20th
edition at http://www.mcconnell21e.com and access the Origin of the
Idea link to Ricardo's concept of comparative advantage to further
your understanding of comparative advantage. Viet Catfish Case
Sixteen years after the end of the Vietnam war, the United States
and Vietnam signed a free trade agreement. In December 2001,
Vietnam agreed to lower import tariffs and restrictions on U.S.
investments in that nation. In return, the U.S. agreed to dismantle
discriminatory trade barriers on Vietnamese exports. The trade pact
was an instant success. Vietnamese exports to the U.S. more than
doubled in the first year after the trade pact was signed, led by
exports of textiles, seafood, shoes, furniture, and commodities.
U.S. investments in Vietnam also surged. Catfish farmers in the
Mississippi Delta weren’t happy about this surge in Viet-U.S.
trade. In fact, they were downright angr y. For well over a decade,
catfish farmers in Mississippi, Arkansas, and Louisiana had been
struggling to preserve their profits. As reported in Chapter 23 of
The Economy Today (Chapter 8 in The Micro Economy Today) low entry
barriers kept persistent pressure on prices and profits. The early
entrepreneurs in the industry had to contend with a stream of
cotton farmers who sought higher returns in catfish farming.
Despite an impressive rise in market demand, prices and profits
stayed low as the industry expanded. Surging Imports The Viet-U.S.
pact intensified competitive pressures on Delta catfish farmers. In
1998, only 575,000 pounds of Vietnamese catfish were imported into
the United States, mostly in the form of frozen fillets. Viet
imports surged to 20 million pounds in 2001 and jumped again to 34
million pounds last year. That was more competition than domestic
catfish farmers could bear. The price of frozen fillets fell by 15
percent in 2001, to a low of 62 cents a pound. Prices kept falling
in 2002, hitting a low of 53 cents a pound at years end. With
average production costs of 65 cents a pound, U.S. catfish farmers
were incurring substantial economic losses. Suddenly, cotton
farming started looking better again. Comparative Advantage
Shifting domestic resources from catfish farming back to cotton
farming is consistent with the principle of comparative advantage.
Most farm-raised U.S. catfish are grown in clay-lined ponds filled
with purified waters from underground wells. The fish are fed
pellets containing soybeans and corn and are subject to regular
USDA health inspections. Vietnamese catfish, by contrast, are grown
in giant holding pens suspended under the free-flowing Mekong river
and other waterways. The Vietnamese production process is much less
expensive, giving Vietnam’s catfish farmers an absolute advantage
over U.S. farmers. Given the relatively high costs of cotton
farming in Vietnam, the Vietnamese also have a decided comparative
advantage in catfish farming. Because of this, both the U.S. and
Vietnam could enjoy more output if the U.S. specialized in cotton
farming and Vietnam specialized in catfish farming. That is exactly
the kind of resource reallocation the surging Vietnamese catfish
exports was causing. Trade Resistance The 13,000 workers in the
U.S. catfish industry don’t want to hear about comparative
advantage. They simply want to keep their jobs. And their employers
want to regain economic profits. They aren’t willing to sacrifice
their own well-being for the sake of cheaper fish and so-called
gains from trade. Economic theory may not be on the side of the
domestic catfish industry, but U.S. politicians certainly are. At
the urging of Trent Lott, the Senate majority leader from
Mississippi, the U.S. Congress decided that of the 2,000 or so
varieties of catfish, only the North American channel variety of
catfish could be labeled as “catfish.” Vietnamese catfish had to be
labeled as “basa” or “tra,” as in the Vietnamese language. To
further discourage consumption of imports, the Catfish Farmers of
America, an industry lobbying group, ran advertisements warning
American consumers that “basa” and “tra” “float a round in Third
World rivers nibbling on who knows what.” Arkansas C o n g ressman
Marion Berry warned that Viet fish might even be contaminated by
Agent orange-- a defoliant sprayed over the Vietnamese countryside
by U.S. f o rces during the Vietnam war. None of these nontariff
barriers halted the influx of Viet catfish however. Dumping Charges
U.S. catfish farmers decided to mount a more direct attack on Viet
catfish. The Catfish Farmers of America filed a complaint with the
U.S. Department of C o m m e rce, charging Vietnam of “dumping”
catfish on U.S. markets. Dumping occurs when foreign producers sell
their p roducts abroad for less than the costs of producing them or
less than prices in their own market. On its face, the complaint
seemed to have no merit. Export prices were no lower than domestic
prices in Vi e t n a m . Plus, Vietnamese farmers were evidently e
a rning economic profits. Hence, neither form of dumping seemed
plausible. The Department of Commerce found a loophole to resolve
this contradiction. C o m m e rce officials decided that Vietnam
was still not a “market econom y.” As a “nonmarket economy” its
prices could not be regarded as re l i a b l e indices of
underlying costs. Instead, the U.S. Department of Commerce would
have to independently assess the “true ” costs of Vietnamese
catfish production. To determine the “true” costs of Vietnamese
catfish farming, U.S. investigators went to Bangladesh! Bangladesh
is widely regarded as a market economy, with a level of development
similar to Vi e t n a m ’s. So Bangladesh prices were assigned to
Vietnamese farmers. With no fully integrated firms and fewer
natural resource advantages, Bangladesh ended up with hypothetical
costs in excess of Vietnamese prices. With this “evidence” in hand,
the Commerce Department concluded in January 2003 that Vietnamese
catfish were indeed being dumped on U.S. markets. Anti-Dumping
Duties To “level the playing field,” the U.S. Commerce Department
leveled temporary import duties (tariffs) of 37-64 percent.
Importers of Viet catfish had to deposit these duties into an
escrow account until the U.S. International Trade Commission (ITC)
reviewed the case. The ITC must not only affirm the practice of
dumping, but must also determine that U.S. catfish farmers have
been materially damaged by such unfair foreign competition. If the
ITC so rules, then the duties become permanent and payable. If the
ITC rejects the dumping or damage charges, the duties are rescinded
and the escrowed payments are refunded. The odds are never good for
foreign producers: The Commerce department ruled in favor of
domestic producers 91 percent of the time and the ITC concurred 80
percent of the time. The catfish case was similarly decided: on
July 23 of this year the ITC unanimously ruled that Viet catfish
had injured U.S. catfish farmers. The temporary duties of 37-64
percent were made permanent and retroactive to January. This
article illustrates the political economy of international trade
and the concept of comparative advantage. Explain Who are the
"Winners" and "Losers" and why as described in this article, and
the effect of "arbitrary government intervention" that circumvents
the workings of free trade initiated by Senator Trent Lott as
described in the article? Use the economic concept of comparative
advantage in your explanation. (10 points)